РЕГИОНАЛЬНЫЙ РЫНОК ТРУДА
E. Marelli, D. Sciulli, M. Signorelli
SKILL MISMATCH OF GRADUATES IN A LOCAL LABOUR MARKET1
In this paper we first review the (potential and actual) role of the Universities for the local economies in which they operate, especially considering the implications deriving from the degree of skill mismatch (over-education) in a local labour market. Then, in the second part of the paper, we realise an empirical investigation based on administrative information of an Italian University matched with the data of the job centres of the local (provincial) labour market in order to reconstruct the characteristics of the university-to-work transitions of graduates. Our results have important policy implications, since for local development it is crucial, among other things, to make the best use of all human resources and especially those with the highest educational level.
Keywords: Local labour market, human capital, skill mismatch, over-education
1. Introduction
The role of education and human capital for economic development has been extensively investigated, both on a national scale and at regional or local levels. It has also been recognized in many policy programmes, at the national and international level, including the Lisbon Agenda and "Europe 2020" within the EU. However, the educational and productive systems can contribute to different degrees of "mismatch" between the knowledge acquired through formal education and the skills demanded by employers: this may cause either youth unemployment or skill-mismatch phenomena, including over-education. In this respect, the importance of appropriate school-to-work transition processes should also be underlined.
In this paper the phenomena of skill mismatch of graduates has been investigated for the case of an Italian local labour market. First of all it should be noted that, in the case of Italy, Alma Laurea provides information on the conditions of graduates (at 1, 3 and 5 years after graduation) of most Italian universities. However, the empirical investigation of the features of the transition to work of graduates of a particular University in a specific territory (like a Province) needs the use of the large databases created by the local "public job centres"2.
1 © Marelli E., Sciulli D., Signorelli M. Text. 2014.
2 According to Italian legislation, it is compulsory for firms
to send complete and detailed information to the local «pub-
In this paper, data from the job centres of the province of Perugia — since January 2004 to July 2009 — are matched with university's data to reconstruct the features of the university-to-work transitions of graduates at the University of Perugia3 in the provincial labour market. By using this statistical information, a previous paper (Sciulli and Signorelli, 47) focused on some characteristics of University-to-work transitions (UTWTs).
In the present paper we complete the previous investigation by considering the characteristics of the skill mismatch. In particular, we focus on the incidence of "good job-matches" of Perugia graduates finding a job in the province of Perugia, and its incidence across some relevant individual characteristics. We define a situation of «good jobmatch» when a graduate is employed in a job attached to a "skilled profession" (identified on the basis of ISCO's classification of occupations).
Our main findings are that the rate of "good matches" differs widely across faculties, also as a consequence of the structure of the local labour market. It also depends on the type of university
lic job centres» (usually there are several «job centres» in each Province) for the different forms of labour market flows (hiring and firing), type of contract (permanent, temporary, etc.) and for both worker and firm characteristics.
3 This is a middle-size Italian University. The overall number of graduates we consider is higher than 30,000 (around 5,000 each year). The average number of students enrolled at the University of Perugia was — in the considered period — near 30,000. The data allow distinguish according to different degrees, faculties, and many other individual and job characteristics.
degrees (pre-reform degrees and post-reform second level degrees are associated with higher frequency), the degree mark (being graduated with the maximum score strongly increases the incidence), time of graduation (being delayed graduated slightly decreases the occurrence) and some other features (gender, nationality, place of residence, age at work, work experience). A two-way analysis based on the intersection of several characteristics is also presented. Our results have important policy implications, since for local development it is crucial, among other things, to make the best use of human resources.
After the literature review (Section 2), we shall illustrate the data base used and the key results of our investigations on Perugia's graduates (Section 3); then Section 4 concludes.
2. Literature Review
The role of education and human capital for economic growth has been extensively investigated in both theoretical and empirical works, especially in the last two studies.1 The positive role of human capital has been detected also in many studies concerning local development. Human capital is a key driver of local and regional development not only because individuals with high skills and knowledge are more productive, but also because productivity of all workers tend to be higher in regions where their peers have high levels of human capital.
In this context, universities can provide an important contribution to regional development, not only in the field of higher education but also — through top level research centres — with respect to social and economic development. Creating knowledge and exchanging this knowledge are central factors for the success of a location, i.e. for a "learning region" (Florida, 20). A region's ability to learn and adapt is influenced by the networks and institutional conditions; "learning by interacting" becomes a key driver of innovations and growth.2 A transfer of innovation and knowledge is beneficial to both the regional enterprises and the universities, also through the promotion of spin-offs and business start-ups. As a high education institution, the university can help to keep a highly qualified workforce in the region and not to migrate (the brain gain is fostered and the brain drain prevented); furthermore, it can provide ser-
1 See, among many others, Lucas (29), Benhabib and Spiegel (5), Krueger and Lindahl (26), De La Fuente and Ciccone (17).
2 There are some links also with the "social capital" approach (Putnam, 41), according to which the relationships between individuals and social groups are fundamental for the economic development of a region or a community.
vices for skill upgrading, that are so important at the local and regional level.3 Among other things, universities are location factors that influence the image and "location quality" of regions. A partnership between the university and the region is often advocated to favour the realization of learning regions within a knowledge-based society (see Strauf and Scherer, 48). In particular, innovation and internationalisation of local firms is fostered by the best practices of the higher education system in collaboration with the regional stakeholders.4
At the individual level, human capital is a prominent element in the effective transition of young people from school to the labour market, for the risk of unemployment they face, their performance at work, and the quality and stability of their position. Notwithstanding that education is a key component of human capital, starting from school and university education, many other ele-ments5 — such as out-of-job training courses, on-the-job training (generic training, specific training, learning-by-doing) and life-long learning — may be important as well; the existence of a "youth experience gap" harms the employability of young people. In most countries, well-educated young adults exhibit higher employment and labour force participation rates, and lower unemployment rates.
The role of human capital for economic development has been recognized in many policy programmes, at the national and international level. The «Lisbon Strategy» (2000) considered the key importance of investment in human capital for creating «more and better jobs». The new "Europe 2020" plan also pays attention to youth labour and education problems: the share of 30-34 years youngsters having completed tertiary or equivalent education should reach at least 40 % at the
3 In fact, adult learners are less mobile than younger students, so skill upgrading provided by universities raises labour productivity and the performance of the local economy. Notice that skill upgrading, lifelong learning, re-skilling and flexible ways of learning are needed because of technical progress and rapidly changing skill requirements in working life, which is itself getting more extended (OECD, 37).
4 In Italy the enduring success of industrial districts depends on the capacity to build broad networks involving universities, research centres, and financial institutions.
5 Thus, the generally adopted empirical measures of human capital, such as years of schooling or level of formal education completed (sometimes distinguishing between the different types of schools and universities) are only near "proxies" (a recent empirical investigation in the case of EU countries is in Marelli and Signorelli, 30). If possible, they should be integrated by the mentioned non-school components as well as by some other elements, like family networks and social background.
end of this decade. In general we can say that appropriate industrial or structural policies can raise the demand for graduated or highly educated workers, demand which is also affected by technical progress, the diffusion of innovations and new organisational methods, the tertiarisation of the economies, etc.
A well-known hypothesis in economic literature is that in the last three decades there has been an increasing demand of educated and skilled workers, because of structural change (e.g. tertiar-isation and financialisation of economies) and a "skilled biased" technical change, due to the diffusion of new technologies: ict, internet, etc. 1 This shift in labour demand has damaged the relative position of unskilled workers, that in any case are hurted also by other phenomena such as globalization (including trade with developing countries, FDI and de-localisations, immigration flows). The damage consists in lower or even declining (at least in relative terms) wages of unskilled workers in the United States and other "flexible" economies and in increasing unemployment in some "rigid" European labour markets. A more recent hypothesis refers to a likely polarization2 of the employment and wage structures, since structural product and demand shifts have increased the relative demand for high and low skilled workers, shrinking the medium-skilled workers across many economic activities.3 In any case, the increase in the demand for skilled labour is not homogeneous in all industries and, particularly at the local level, might concern certain jobs and professions rather than the aggregate economy.
If we now turn to the supply side of education, in particular of higher education, we can notice that in many countries of the world there have been constantly rising investments in education, hence in the supply of educated and skilled workers. This is a consequence of a growth, in many countries, of families' income but also of welfare expenditures, specifically devoted to education, training and human capital formation. Also reforms of education and university systems have often favored the enrollment of young people.
1 Initially discussed in the '90s by Krugman, Katz, Murphy, Machin, and many other economists (see e.g. Nickell, 35).
2 See Autor et al. (3), Goos et al. (21), Michaels et al. (33). The phenomenon has become common also in developing countries: see e.g. Helmy (23).
3 One explanation is the "routinization" hypothesis, according to which computers and new technologies complement both high skilled jobs and low skilled interpersonal tasks, but substitute for middle skilled (manual and clerical) tasks (Autor et al., 3). Another explanation is the privatization of some former "public" services and productions.
Regarding Europe, we should recall the "Bologna Process" started in 1999; the "Bologna Declaration" was signed in June 1999 at Bologna (Italy) by the ministers of 29 European countries and it calls for the establishment of a cycle system of study programmes and degrees: a first study programme called Bachelor — in the Anglo-Saxon world — and a second leading to a Master. In the majority of countries, the following reforms produced a three-year first level degree and a two-year second level degree (the doctoral studies are the third stage of the Bologna model).4 If we should judge about the success of this model, we must recognize that the realization of closer and better relationships between higher education and the world of work is a prominent objective (e.g. Teichler, 49). However for many aspects the Bologna Process is still ongoing, with significant country differences (European Commission, 18).
A possible cause of high youth unemployment and low quality employment of young people is still the mismatch between the knowledge acquired through formal education and the skills demanded by employers. Many young people are unemployed or cannot find jobs which are adequate to their educational path despite a medium-high level of formal education; a key reason is lack of experience (Pastore, 39). The characteristics of both educational systems5 and the university-to-work-transition (UTWT) institutions are relevant; of course, also propitious labour market institutions may favor the employability of young people.6
Schomburg and Teichler (45) present very recent and complete researches regarding the "em-ployability and mobility" of graduates in Europe.7
4 In Italy a long and complex "reform phase" started with Law n. 509/1999 and was first implemented in 2001 with the "3plus2" track system. In short, the Italian system moved from a single four/five year degree to a two-tier system characterised by a three year degree (first cycle, "laurea triennale") and an additional two year degree (secondary cycle, "laurea magistralis"). Notice that a persisting feature of the Italian system is the "legal" value of University degrees (e.g. Cappellari and Lucifora, 12).
5 As to the education systems in Europe, that can be classified according to their flexibility vs. rigidity and to their "dual" vs. "sequential" approach to training, see Caroleo and Pastore (13).
6 There are many definitions of "employability". For example, the "Bologna Follow-up Group" defined employability as "the ability to gain initial employment, to maintain employment, and to be able to move around within the labour market". As to the more general school-to-work processes and trends see Quintini et al. (42).
7 In addition to two general assessments of the Bologna Process, the volume includes country studies regarding Austria, the Czech Republic, France, Germany, Hungary, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland and the UK.
Some other researches investigated, in the European context and from different perspectives, the recent changes in higher education and the complex features of university-to-work transitions (e.g. Mora, 34; OECD, 36; Schomburg, 44; Schomburg and Teichler, 45; Teichler 49, 50; Little 28). In particular, Teichler (50) argues that even the more complex researches on the relationships between higher education and the world of work are not yet beneficial for a dialogue with practitioners about the future of higher education. A huge literature focus on individual countries and particular topics of the university-to-work transitions, e.g. examining the positive role of "university career services" or comparing the transitions from higher education to work in different countries.
In the case of Italy, some key details on the Italian reforms and their consequences — e.g. on enrolment decisions and UTWTs — are discussed in Bratti, Broccolini and Staffolani (5), Brunello and Cappellari (9), Cappellari and Lucifora (12). As for the very recent researches, Cammelli et al. (11) highlight the mixed outcomes of the Bologna Process in Italy by using the well known Alma Laurea database, while the positive role played by Alma Laurea in favouring UTWTs has been investigated by Bagues and Sylos Labini (4). Moreover, Biggeri et al. (6) investigate the factors determining UTWTs by adopting a multilevel approach to the analysis of the time to obtain the first job.1 Some other studies (mostly published in Italian language) refer to Italian graduates, at national or regional/local level.
An additional strand of literature that is worth to recall refers to the "overeducation" phenomenon, that describes the extent to which an individual possesses a level of education in excess of that which is required for her particular job (McGuiness, 31; Groot and van den Brink 22; Leuven and Oosterbeek, 27). Overeducation is potentially costly to the individual (who is less satisfied with her job and more likely to quit), the firm (because of lower productivity) and the (local) economy. At a macroeconomic level, national welfare is potentially lower than would be the case if the skills of overeducated workers were fully utilized. Individual overeducated workers, because of the fact that a proportion of their educational investment is unproductive, are likely to earn a lower return on their educational investment; overedu-cated workers are in some way less able relative
1 Pozzoli (40) focuses on the transition from university to first job for Italian graduates, taking into account graduates' characteristics (before the implementation of the Bologna Process) and the effects relating to degree subject.
to their adequately matched counterparts, therefore, lower wages are a reflection of lower ability/ productivity.
At a macro level, a reason of overeducation is the relative growth of supply of highly educated workers versus the growth in demand.2 Overeducation can be assessed3 by comparing the required education on the basis of their job title (using information provided by classifications such as the Standard Occupational Classification System) and the individuals actual level of education. A recent meta-analysis shows that the mean value of the incidence of overeducation is about 22 %, i.e. 7 % below what results from subjective measures based on workers' self-assessment (see McGuiness, 31); of course, different methods of measurement lead to different measures of over-education. Moreover, in the mentioned study there are no indications that the incidence of overedu-cation has been rising over time. Regarding wages, the analysis highlight the lower returns to surplus education and an "overeducation penalty".
A higher incidence of overeducation is found for the European countries — concerning specifically tertiary graduates — by Croce and Ghignoni (16), with the largest number of countries concentrated between 30 % and 40 % (but some of them including Germany are above 50 %). This study is also interesting since it shows that the increase of the supply of qualified labour does not cause per se overeducation, but there is an important role played by the demand for qualified labour; moreover, overeducation operates as a short-term adjustment mechanism following the economic cycle.
2 It can also be caused by imperfect matching in the labour market due to a wrong distribution of educated workers by field of study, to spatial mismatch or to other imperfections (Croce and Ghignoni, 16). Notice that "horizontal overeducation" is likely in certain countries, due to the low degree of orientation of high school diploma students, the scant integration of the educational system with the labour market and — at least in Italy — the high share of graduates in humanities and other arts degrees. Also delayed graduation increases the chances of overeducation (Aina and Pastore, 1). According to McGuinness and Sloane (32), Italy exhibits one of the highest shares of both over-educated workers (23 % at the time of their first job) and "over-skilling" (21 %).
3 An alternative is to consider measures of "excess schooling", i.e. overeducated are graduates who do a job for which the number of years of schooling required is lower than that completed. There are also subjective measures of overeducation, that have been criticized for different reasons. On the other hand, the occupational dictionary-based objective measures are open to the criticism that occupations may contain a number of skill levels, so people with the same job title may be doing very different jobs (see McGuiness, 31).
It is remarkable to note that according to some research (e.g. Buchel and van Ham, 10) the risk of overeducation is higher for workers in small regional labour markets; this finding is obtained after controlling in the regressions for distance to work (workers living in rural locations are more likely to be overeducated). Thus spatial mobility is a potential way of avoiding overeducation; otherwise, in presence of spatial and other types of rigidities in the labour market (e.g. when employers are unwilling to modify their production processes to fully utilize the skills of their employees), if the supply of educated labour exceeds their demand, the risk of overeducation is real.
Finally, it is important to emphasize that skill mismatch may be one reason for the high youth unemployment rate. Notice that youth unemployment rates are generally higher than the adult ones (Blanchflower and Freeman, 8); in Europe, they are twice or three times as high as the adult rates, with significant differences across countries. Youth unemployment has further risen after the recent global and Eurozone crisis1 (e.g. ILO, 24 and 25; European Commission, 19); also graduates experimented a general worsening in the transition to work processes, with significant country and regional differences (as for the Italian case, see AlmaLaurea, 2). Scarpetta et al. (43) highlight that the crises exacerbate a number of structural problems that affect the transition from school to work: the decline in GDP turns after some months into a reduction of labour demand; in this situation school-leavers are competing with more job-seekers for fewer vacancies, while the young people already in the labour market are generally among the first to lose their jobs, mainly due to the higher diffusion of temporary contracts2 (see e.g. Choudhry, Marelli and Signorelli 15). Hence, youth unemployment rates are more sensitive to the business cycle than adult unemployment rates. O'Higgins (38) warns that the key problem is not only that young people are more vulnerable to the crises but also that these effects are likely to be more long-lasting for the young; long periods of unemployment erode the skills of young workers, reduce their employability, cause a permanent loss of human capital.
1 In general, the impact on unemployment — specifically on youth unemployment — is greater in the case of financial crises (Choudhry, Marelli and Signorelli, 15).
2 In the EU, just before the crisis in 2008, 41.8 % of young people were in temporary employment compared to 14.4 % for all employees. The incidence of youth in temporary employment has risen to 44.3 % after the crisis. In many countries (for example in Italy), practically all new employment opportunities in this period have been temporary (O'Higgins, 38).
3. Data and Descriptive Analysis
3.1. Data
Our empirical analysis is based on a matched-sample between the University of Perugia administrative information and the data from the job-centres of the province of Perugia. This allows us to reconstruct the UTWT of graduates at the University of Perugia since January 2004 to July 2009 that have found a job in the province of Perugia3. Our analysis include both graduates that have obtained a pre-reform degree (PreRD) and graduates that have obtained a post-reform degree (both first level -PRFLD- and second level -PRSLD-, including both the unique cycle second level degree and the magistralis degree)4.
Tables 1a and 1b present information regarding the share of graduates of the University of Perugia, distinguishing according to the faculty and degrees, that have found at least a job in the province of Perugia in the period ranging from 2004 to 2009.
Looking at the table above, the percentage of graduates working in the province of Perugia is quite homogenous among faculties (with the exception of the faculties of Law, Medicine and Veterinary Science). Table 2 reports differences in employment rates in the province of Perugia according to the province of residence, showing relevant heterogeneities.
3.2. Skill matches of Perugia graduates in the Perugia labour market
This section provides descriptive evidence of incidence of good job-matches of Perugia graduates finding a job in the province of Perugia, and its incidence across some relevant individual characteristics. According to our definition, a good job-match exists if a graduate is employed in a job attached to a skilled profession. Skilled professions are identified by the categorization provided by the International Standard Classification of Occupations 1988 (ISCO-88) as reported in Table 3, that has been adopted by the International Labour Organization in 1987. Specifically, jobs attached to occupations classified in the first three levels (legislators, senior officials, managers, professionals, technicians and associate professionals) of the ISCO-88 skill classification, are identified as skilled jobs.
3 Since matches outside to the province of Perugia are not identifiable, durations of censored spells are likely to be over-estimated. This may have consequences in terms of timing comparison among faculties in case the placement of graduates from different faculties is heterogeneous across provinces.
4 Considering the timing of implementation of Law 509/1999, the post-reform degrees involved graduates enrolled at the University of Perugia since 2001.
Source: our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres data.
Table 1b
Graduates at the University of Perugia and employed in the province of Perugia
Table 1a
Graduates at the University of Perugia and employed in the province of Perugia
Pre-reform degree Post-reform first level degree
Non-working in the province of Perugia Working in the province of Perugia Graduates % Employed in the province of Perugia Non-working in the province of Perugia Working in the province of Perugia Graduates % Employed in the province of Perugia
Agriculture 266 188 454 41.41 % 250 136 386 35.23 %
Economics 870 551 1421 38.78 % 1282 671 1953 34.36 %
Pharmacy 440 197 637 30.93 % 80 32 112 28.57 %
Law 1409 343 1752 19.58 % 413 83 496 16.73 %
Engineering 956 704 1660 42.41 % 865 348 1213 28.69 %
Arts and Philosophy 2355 1251 3606 34.69 % 2247 743 2990 24.85 %
Medicine 1016 172 1188 14.48 % 683 669 1352 49.48 %
Veterinary Science 361 34 395 8.61 % 8 3 11 27.27 %
Education 459 450 909 49.50 % 771 340 1111 30.60 %
Mathematics, Physics and Natural Science 616 430 1046 41.11 % 765 284 1049 27.07 %
Political Science 404 260 664 39.16 % 797 303 1100 27.55 %
Total 9152 4580 13732 33.35 % 8161 3612 11773 30.68 %
Post-reform second level degree Total
Non-working in the province of Perugia Working in the province of Perugia Graduates % Employed in the province of Perugia Non-working in the province of Perugia Working in the province of Perugia Graduates % Employed in the province of Perugia
Agriculture 88 73 161 45.34 % 604 397 1001 39.66 %
Economics 386 287 673 42.64 % 2538 1509 4047 37.29 %
Pharmacy 110 46 156 29.49 % 630 275 905 30.39 %
Law 313 65 378 17.20 % 2135 491 2626 18.70 %
Engineering 284 305 589 51.78 % 2105 1357 3462 39.20 %
Arts and Philosophy 571 301 872 34.52 % 5173 2295 7468 30.73 %
Medicine 436 68 504 13.49 % 2135 909 3044 29.86 %
Veterinary Science 111 8 119 6.72 % 480 45 525 8.57 %
Education 188 326 514 63.42 % 1418 1116 2534 44.04 %
Mathematics, Physics and Natural Science 171 111 282 39.36 % 1552 825 2377 34.71 %
Political Science 223 105 328 32.01 % 1424 668 2092 31.93 %
Total 2881 1695 4576 37.04 % 20194 9887 30081 32.87 %
Source: our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres data.
Table 4 includes information about the descriptive statistics of the sample under analysis. It includes information about the characteristics of 7604 Perugia graduates employed in the province of Perugia, for a total of 28245 job relationships in the period January 2004 — June 2009. Specifically, we note that the incidence of good job-matches is about 56 %. In what follow we present the distribution of the incidence of good job-matches across the following characteristics: faculty, type
of degree, delayed graduation, degree mark, gender, province of residence, nationality, working age, and first job-experience after graduation.
The following Tables provide information about the incidence of good job-matches (I) for Perugia graduates in the period under analysis. It is interesting to note that the complementary values of the incidence (1-I) represents the over-education rate. This seems important in a comparative perspective with previous studies on this topic.
Table 2
Graduates at the University of Perugia, residence and employment
Not residents in the province of Perugia Residents in the province of Perugia
Non-working in the province of Perugia Working in the province of Perugia Graduates % Employed in the province of Perugia Non-working in the province of Perugia Working in the province of Perugia Graduates % Employed in the province of Perugia
Agriculture 403 121 524 23.09 % 201 276 477 57.86 %
Economics 1,694 271 1,965 13.79 % 844 1238 2082 59.46 %
Pharmacy 485 73 558 13.08 % 145 202 347 58.21 %
Law 1,327 118 1,445 8.17 % 808 373 1181 31.58 %
Engineering 1,139 289 1,428 20.24 % 966 1068 2034 52.51 %
Arts and Philosophy 3,875 670 4,545 14.74 % 1298 1625 2923 55.59 %
Medicine 1,279 116 1,395 8.32 % 856 793 1649 48.09 %
Veterinary Science 368 20 388 5.15 % 112 25 137 18.25 %
Education 993 184 1,177 15.63 % 425 932 1357 68.68 %
Mathematics, Physics and Natural Science 868 173 1,041 16.62 % 684 652 1336 48.80 %
Political Science 858 147 1,005 14.63 % 566 521 1087 47.93 %
Total 13289 2182 15471 14.10 % 6905 7705 14610 52.74 %
Source: our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres data.
tially decreasing the probability of being in a good job-matches and vice-versa.
Table 5 also provides the T-tests for the equality of proportions between the specific sub-group under analysis compared with the remaining observations. According to the faculty variable, Pharmacy (57.55 %) determines an incidence very close the average value, while Maths, Physics and Natural Science (62.30 %), Engineering (66.76 %) and, overall, Medicine (70.27 %) and Education (77.76 %), are associated to higher incidences. Conversely, Arts and Philosophy (50.86 %), Agriculture (46.15 %), Veterinary Science (41.28 %), Law (38.63 %), Economics (37.48 %) and Political Science (36.44 %), are associated to lower incidences, indicating higher risk of over-education. Among the underlying motives possibly explaining this strong heterogeneity in the incidence at faculty level, the structure of the local labour market is likely to play a relevant one.
The type of degree also determines a relevant heterogeneity in terms of incidence of good jobmatches. Pre-reform degree (PreRD) and, overall, Post-reform second level degree (PRSLD) are associated to higher incidence with respect to the average value, respectively 61.75 % and 70.95 %. Indeed, not surprisingly, the Post-reform first level degree is associated to a lower incidence (44.90 %). This is possibly indicative that firstlevel graduates are more prone to accept unskilled jobs or, alternatively, that employers tend to associate to this type of degree a lower skill content (negative signaling) that reduce the op-
Table 3
Classification of occupations ISCO-88 and job-matches for graduates
Occupations ISCO-88 Skill classification Job-Match
Legislators, senior officials and managers 1 Good
Professionals 2 Good
Technicians and associate professionals 3 Good
Clerks 4 Bad
Service, shop and market sales workers 5 Bad
Agricultural and fishery workers 6 Bad
Craft and related trade workers 7 Bad
Plant and machine operators and assemblers 8 Bad
Elementary occupations 9 Bad
Source: International Standard Classification of Occupations 1988
Table 5 presents the incidence of good jobmatches according to the relevant characteristics. Figure 1 graphs the information contained in Table 5, where the central value is set to the average incidence (56.37 %). It follows that histograms lying on the left of the central value refer to characteristics associated to lower incidences, while histograms lying on the right of the central value refer to characteristics associated to higher incidences, i.e., respectively, characteristics poten-
Table 4
Descriptive Statistics
Mean Std Dev.
Skilled job 0.56 0.50
Agriculture 0.03 0.18
Economics 0.12 0.33
Pharmacy 0.03 0.16
Law 0.05 0.22
Engineering 0.09 0.28
Arts and Philosophy 0.27 0.44
Medicine 0.08 0.27
Veterinary Science 0.00 0.06
Education 0.18 0.39
Maths, Physics and Natural Science 0.08 0.28
Political Science 0.06 0.24
Pre-reform degree 0.51 0.50
Post-reform first level degree 0.38 0.49
Post-reform second level degree 0.11 0.31
Delayed graduation 0.73 0.44
Maximum degree mark 0.30 0.46
Male 0.32 0.47
Perugia 0.81 0.39
Italian 0.98 0.14
Working age less than 30 0.69 0.46
First job 0.27 0.44
Year of graduation 2004 0.20 0.40
Year of graduation 2005 0.23 0.42
Year of graduation 2006 0.23 0.42
Year of graduation 2007 0.19 0.39
Year of graduation 2008 0.12 0.32
Year of graduation 2009 0.03 0.18
Table 5
Skill matches by characteristics
I T-test
Observed percentage of being in a good job-match 56.37 %
Agriculture 46.15 % 6.55
Economics 37.48 % 24.41
Pharmacy 57.55 % -0.65
Law 38.63 % 14.25
Engineering 66.76 % -10.83
Faculty Arts and Philosophy 50.86 % 11.31
Medicine 70.27 % -13.83
Veterinary Science 41.28 % 3.18
Education 77.76 % -34.89
Maths, Physics and Natural Science 62.30 % -6.04
Political Science 36.44 % 17.38
Pretreform degree 61.75 % -18.78
Post-reform first level 44.90 % 30.87
Type of degree degree
Post-reform second 70.95 % -17.40
level degree
Delayed No 59.66 %
graduation Yes 55.16 % 6.77
Degree mark Less than maximum 51.07 %
Maximum 68.53 % -27.57
Gender Female 60.24 %
Male 48.05 % 19.36
Province of Out of Perugia 49.02 %
residence Perugia 58.11 % -12.14
Nationality Out of Italy 29.33 %
Italy 56.96 % -13.54
Working age Age at least 30 64.80 %
Age less than 30 52.66 % 19.07
First job No 57.49 %
Yes 53.35 % 6.22
Source: our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres' data. Note. T-tests refer to the difference of the average of a sub-group with the average of other sub-groups considered as a whole.
Source: our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres' data.
portunity for graduates of being employed in a skilled job.
Being delayed graduated slightly decreases the incidence, 55.16 % against 59.66 % for not delayed graduates. Even if it is small, this difference is statistically significant. Moreover, this finding agrees with those of Aina and Pastore (2012). Much stronger is the difference in the incidence of good job-matches according to the degree mark. Being graduated with the maximum score strongly increases the incidence: 68.53 % against 51.07 %, indicating that "better" students are more likely to be employed in skilled jobs. Quite surprisingly gender matters, favoring females. Specifically, the incidence of good job-matches is higher for females rather than males (60.24 % against 48.05 %). This seems to indicate that males would accept unskilled jobs to work, while females are more selective.
Also being resident in the Perugia province is associated to a higher incidence (58.11 % against
49.02 %). Among others, a possible explanation to this result is related to the role of social/informal networks in finding a (better) job. Similarly, being Italian slightly increases the incidence (56.96 %), while being a foreign graduate strongly decreases the incidence of good job-matches (29.33 %). This specific characteristic is associated to the lowest incidence, among those found here.
Looking at the age in which the job relationship begins, we find that the incidence is lower for graduates aged less than 30 years old (52.66 %) rather than for those aged at least 30 years old (64.80 %). Finally, graduates at their first job experiences after graduation come across a lower inci-
Skill matches
.00%
30.00%
Ag
c o
No
e less t
Age at least 30
Italy
E m- v
O QJ 'w £ u £
cu —£=
CU
O
tuo œ cu _Q
cu TO — "O 'S Û
CU 2
_Q_5Û_
° S
CU s-CL ÛÛ
tri
Out of Italy
Perugia
Out of Perugia
Maximum Lessthan maximum
Post-reform second level degree Post-reform first I
Pre-r
Maths, Physics and Na
Female
Ye* No
eform degree
tural Science Education
Medicine Artsan|d Philosophy Engineering
Pharmacy
Agriculture
40.00%
50.00%
60.00%
Skill matches
70.00%
80.00%
Source. Our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres' data. Fig. 1. Skill matches by characteristics (Average value: 56.37 %)
Table 6a
Skill matches and faculties, by characteristics
Gender Degree Type Delayed graduation Degree mark
Faculty Female Male PreRD PRFLD PRSLD No Yes No Max Max
Agriculture 52.16 % 39.57 % 54.77 % 35.08 % 63.16 % 61.75 % 40.75 % 39.87 % 56.08 %
Economics 37.89 % 36.92 % 49.91 % 29.88 % 41.69 % 40.59 % 35.95 % 35.72 % 44.74 %
Pharmacy 55.33 % 64.02 % 60.14 % 32.08 % 75.36 % 61.35 % 56.48 % 54.09 % 64.73 %
Law 44.71 % 24.61 % 36.53 % 43.64 % 56.70 % 51.56 % 37.42 % 38.08 % 44.12 %
Engineering 63.77 % 67.64 % 75.30 % 52.90 % 74.38 % 68.15 % 66.45 % 64.67 % 75.37 %
Arts and Philosophy 55.60 % 34.60 % 59.08 % 33.25 % 51.96 % 41.88 % 53.50 % 41.66 % 66.71 %
Medicine 73.43 % 65.09 % 52.22 % 72.18 % 71.30 % 74.56 % 61.55 % 61.75 % 83.00 %
Veterinary Science 56.06 % 18.60 % 29.69 % 60.00 % 50.00 % 64.29 % 37.89 % 29.51 % 56.25 %
Education 80.40 % 50.00 % 81.96 % 52.38 % 92.22 % 82.91 % 76.03 % 76.22 % 80.41 %
Maths, Physics and Natural Science 62.05 % 62.71 % 70.07 % 50.77 % 74.14 % 70.25 % 60.23 % 58.72 % 70.81 %
Political Science 41.82 % 24.86 % 37.64 % 35.06 % 37.76 % 41.34 % 34.67 % 34.53 % 43.43 %
Source. Our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres' data.
Table 6b
Skill matches and faculties, by characteristics
Nationality Perugia Working age First job
Faculty Foreign Italian No Yes Over 29 Less 30 No Yes
Agriculture 25.00 % 46.24 % 47.04 % 45.75 % 56.00 % 41.23 % 44.13 % 50.85 %
Economics 13.02 % 38.71 % 32.05 % 38.59 % 46.35 % 35.27 % 34.55 % 43.91 %
Pharmacy 36.36 % 57.87 % 58.86 % 57.19 % 63.67 % 54.32 % 59.96 % 53.21 %
Law 23.08 % 39.19 % 20.39 % 45.60 % 41.52 % 35.81 % 38.21 % 39.71 %
Engineering 52.94 % 66.86 % 70.00 % 66.03 % 71.81 % 63.96 % 67.03 % 66.35 %
Arts and Philosophy 44.21 % 50.94 % 44.21 % 52.73 % 63.89 % 45.82 % 52.28 % 46.39 %
Medicine 52.27 % 71.01 % 53.50 % 72.32 % 79.44 % 67.13 % 70.04 % 70.70 %
Veterinary Science — 41.28 % 41.67 % 40.82 % 35.56 % 45.31 % 41.27 % 41.30 %
Education 14.29 % 78.20 % 75.19 % 78.15 % 84.30 % 74.77 % 80.66 % 61.93 %
Maths, Physics and Natural Science 45.95 % 62.57 % 61.57 % 62.50 % 69.17 % 57.75 % 62.43 % 61.97 %
Political Science 19.57 % 37.39 % 34.80 % 36.85 % 37.40 % 36.06 % 35.65 % 38.33 %
Source. Our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres' data.
dence (53.35 %) when compared with other graduates (57.49 %). Both results associated at the age and the first-job variables are possibly indicative that young workers (in terms of age and job experiences) are more prone to accept unskilled jobs to enter in the labour market.
Tables 6a, 6b, 7a and 7b repeat the analysis presented above, but they propose a deeper investigation by using two-way tables. The role of faculties (6a and 6b) and of the types of degree (7a and 7b) have been emphasized. For the sake of brevity, we just focus on sub-groups diverging significantly from patterns emerged above.
In this view, from a gender perspective, we find that males and females show a similar incidence of good job-matches if they are graduated in Economics and Engineering, while the incidence is higher for males in case they are graduated in Pharmacy. From a type of degree perspec-
tive, we find a bad performance for graduates in Law in the pre-reform period, while the post-reform first level degree is not associated to a negative incidence rate (compared with other degrees) for the faculties of Veterinary Science and Political Science. Delayed graduation is associated to a relevant lower incidence rate for graduates at the faculties of Agriculture, Law, Medicine and Veterinary Science (from -13 % to -27 % when compared with not delayed graduation). Conversely, delayed graduation is associated to a higher incidence rate for graduated at the faculty of Arts and Philosophy. Being graduated with the maximum degree mark strongly increases the incidence rate for graduates at the faculties of Medicine and Arts and Philosophy.
Being a foreign graduate determines a very strong disadvantage for graduates at the faculty of Education (the incidence rate is 14.3 %) when
Table 7a
Skill matches and degree type, by characteristics
Gender Delayed graduation Degree mark
Degree Type Female Male No Yes No Max Max
Pre-Reform Degree 65.16 % 52.87 % 63.71 % 61.61 % 57.25 % 72.30 %
Post-Reform First Level Degree 47.39 % 41.04 % 51.91 % 40.08 % 40.87 % 59.10 %
Post-Reform Second Level Degree 74.22 % 61.14 % 72.90 % 65.76 % 69.74 % 71.72 %
Source. Our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres' data.
Table 7b
Skill matches and degree type, by characteristics
Nationality Perugia Working age First job
Degree Type Foreign Italian No Yes Over 29 Less 30 No Yes
Pre-Reform Degree 27.49 % 62.16 % 54.68 % 63.51 % 64.33 % 59.53 % 64.32 % 53.99 %
Post-Reform First Level Degree 27.98 % 45.49 % 38.34 % 46.34 % 54.48 % 43.67 % 42.80 % 49.72 %
Post-Reform Second Level Degree 41.18 % 71.62 % 56.21 % 74.48 % 86.28 % 66.21 % 72.67 % 65.76 %
Source. Our elaboration on University of Perugia administrative information and Perugia job centres' data.
compared to Italian graduates (78.2 %). The advantage in terms of incidence rate for graduates resident in the province of Perugia is stronger for those graduated at the faculties of Law and Medicine. This result seems to suggest the relevance of social/informal networks for specific professions (intergenerational transmission of professions). Being young is associated to a higher incidence for graduates at the faculty of Veterinary Science, while being at the first job experience is particularly negative in terms of incidence of good- job-matches for graduates at the faculty of Education.
About the intersection of degree types and other relevant characteristics, sub-groups diverge in a relevant way from the standard patterns showed above in the following cases. While the disadvantage of males in terms of good jobmatches is quite constant across degree types, we note that being delayed graduated is associated to lower incidences for the post-reform degrees, while it seems to be less relevant for pre-reform degree graduates. On the other side, the maximum degree mark seems to be quite irrelevant for post-reform second level degree graduates in terms of incidence of good job-matches.
Differences in incidence associated to nationality is less relevant for post-reform first level degree graduates, while being resident in the Perugia province seems to be most relevant in terms of incidence for the post-reform second level degree graduates. Being youth (less than 30 years old) penalizes more in terms of incidence for post-reform graduates, while being at the first job is associated to a higher incidence for post-reform first level degree graduates, a finding countervailing results in other sub-groups.
4. Conclusions and policy implications
In this paper we reviewed the literature about the importance of human capital for economic growth and also for local development. In this context, the role played by universities in creating or supporting a "learning region" has been stressed. The benefits of high human capital, however, can be reaped if there are good matches between the skills acquired at school, in particular at the university level, and the characteristics of jobs. But in some instances a skill mismatch can occur, even causing the "overeducation" phenomenon. All this can also contribute to high and persistent youth unemployment rates, that have recently grown as a consequence of the financial and economic crisis.
In the empirical part of the paper, we have produced original results on the university-to-work transitions (UTWTs) in the case of Perugia, as University institution and as provincial labour market, focusing on skill mismatch. University administrative information and data from the job centres of the province have been matched to reconstruct some characteristics of the UTWTs of graduates since January 2004 to July 2009. In the analyzed period about 33 % of graduates of the University of Perugia have found a job in the province of Perugia.
In particular, we have focused on the incidence of "good job-matches", of Perugia graduates finding a job in the province of Perugia, and its incidence across some relevant individual characteristics. A good job-match exists if a graduate is employed in a job attached to a "skilled profession" (identified on the basis of ISCO's classification of occupations). The mean incidence of good jobmatches is about 56 %.
Our main detailed findings are the following. First of all, the rate of "good matches" differs widely across faculties, also as a consequence of the structure of the local labour market: it is higher for Education, Medicine, Engineering and Maths, Physics and Natural Sciences; it is lower for Political Sciences, Economics, Law, Agriculture, Veterinary Science, and Arts and Philosophy.
It also depends on: (i) the type of university degrees: pre-reform degrees and post-reform second level degrees are associated with higher frequency; (ii) the degree mark: being graduated with the maximum score strongly increases the incidence; (iii) time of graduation: being delayed graduated slightly decreases the occurrence. Some other relevant features are the following: (iv) gender: females perform better than males; (v) nationality: foreign graduates present the highest incidence of bad matches; (vi) place of residence: good matches are higher for residents in Perugia's province; (vii) age at work: young graduates (less than 30 years old when work begins) behave better; (viii) work experience: there is a slight advantage for experienced graduates. A two-way analysis based on the intersection of several characteristics is also presented and allows to highlight further empirical evidence.
Our results have important policy implications, since for local development it is crucial to make the best use of human resources. There are two fundamental ways to reduce the incidence of the skill mismatch in a small region such as the Province of Perugia (but similar hints can be provided for many other middle-sized provinces in Italy). First of all, the transition from university to
local economic activities should be supported by appropriate public and private services (orientation, guidance, placement, UTWT agencies, etc.); in general, there is a need for developing more fertile links between universities and the local labour market; in addition, an adequate monitoring of the (local and general) UTWT processes is necessary also for designing a better «teaching supply». Secondarily, spatial mobility should be encouraged when specific professions and skills — acquired at local universities — cannot be matched by adequate jobs "in loco", while the local government should assist the incoming skilled workers (through transport, housing and other public services); extending this conclusion to the overall Italian case, we can state that the "brain drain" would not be a big problem if we could attract — at least in certain professions or for particular jobs — a flow of skilled workers from abroad.
A more general key policy implication (especially for the national government but also for regional/local authorities) regards the need to favor a better evolution of the productive specialization of the Italian economy in order to increase the quantity and quality of the labour demand of graduates, taking also into account of the role of globalization in shaping the «international division of labour». In this respect, fiscal policies promoting higher and better (private and public) R&D investment — driving the quality of the innovation processes — are of crucial importance, and they have to be accompanied with measures encouraging a significant dimensional growth — in both «value added» and «skilled employment» — of the SMEs.
Acknowledgements
Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the International Workshop on «Partners in Innovation. The Role of Knowledge Institutions and Universities in Local Development» (University of Trento, December 10-11 2012) and at a Seminar at the University of Perugia (Department of Economics, October 10 2013). We thank the participants to the above conference and seminar for their useful comments and suggestions.
References
1. Aina C., Pastore F. (2012). Delayed Graduation and Overeducation: A Test of the Human Capital Model versus the Screening Hypothesis. IZA Discussion Paper, 6413.
2. Alma Laurea. (2011). Indagine sulla Condizione Occupazionale dei Laureati in Italia. Available at: www.almalaurea.it.
3. Autor D. H., Katz L. F, Kearney, M. S. (2006). The Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 96 (2), 189-94.
4. Bagues M. F., Sylos-Labini M. (2009). The Impact of AlmaLaurea on the University-to-Work Transition. NBER Working Paper, 13621.
5. Benhabib J., Spiegel M. (1994). The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate CrossCountry Data, Journal of Monetary Economics, 34 (2), 143-173.
6. Biggeri L., Bini M., Grilli L. (2001).The Transition from University to Work: A Multilevel Approach to the Analysis of the Time to Obtain the First Job. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society). 164: 293-305.
7. Bratti, M., Broccolini, C., Staffolani S. (2010). Higher Education Reform, Student Time Allocation and Academic Performance in Italy: Evidence from a Faculty of Economics. Rivista Italiana degli Economisti, 15 (2), 275-304.
8. Blanchflower D.G., Freeman R. (2000). Youth Employment and Joblessness, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL
9. Brunello G., Cappellari L. (2008). The Labour Market Effects of Alma Mater: Evidence from Italy. Economics of Education Review, 27 (5), 564-574.
10. Buchel F., van Ham M. (2002). Overeducation, Regional Labour Markets and Spatial Flexibility. IZA Discussion Paper. No.
424.
11. Cammelli A., Antonelli G., di Francia A., Gasperoni, G., Sgarzi M. (2011). Mixed Outcomes of the Bologna Process in Italy. In Schomburg H. & Teichler U. (Eds.) cit.
12. Cappellari L., Lucifora C. (2009). The "Bologna Process" and College Enrolment Decisions. Labour Economics. 16 (6), 638647.
13. Caroleo F. E., Pastore F. (2007). The youth experience gap: explaining differences across EU countries. Universita di Perugia, Quaderni del Dipartimento di Economia, Finanza e Statistica, 41.
14. Choudhry M.T., Marelli E., Signorelli M. (2012). The Impact of Financial Crises on Youth Unemployment Rate. International Journal of Manpower, 33, 1, 76-95.
15. Choudhry M.T., Marelli E., Signorelli M. (2013). Youth and the total unemployment rate: The impact of policies and institutions. Rivista internazionale di Scienze Sociali, 121 (1), 63-86
16. Croce G., Ghignoni E. (2012). Demand and Supply of Skilled Labour and Overeducation in Europe: A Country-level Analysis. Comparative Economic Studies, 54, 413-439.
17. De La Fuente A., Ciccone A. (2003). Human Capital in a Global and Knowledge-Based Economy, Final report for the European Commission, Directorate-General for Employment and Social Affairs, Luxembourg
18. European Commission — Eurydice (2010). Focus on Higher Education in Europe 2010 — The Impact of the Bologna Process. Brussels: Eurydice.
19. European Commission (2011). Youth Employment Measures. European Employment Observatory Review. Luxembourg.
20. Florida R. (1995). Towards the learning region. Futures 5, 527-536
21. Goos M., Manning A., Salomons A. (2009). Job Polarization in Europe. American Economic Review 99 (2), 58-63.
22. Groot W. , Maassen van den Brink H. (2000). Overeducation in the labour market: A metaanalysis. Economics of Education Review 19 (2), 149-158.
23. Helmy O. (2012). Skill Demand Polarization in Egypt, WP n. 168.
24. ILO (2010). Global Employment Trends. Geneva: International Labour Organization.
25. ILO (2010). Global Employment Trends for Youth. Special issue on the impact of global economic crisis on youth. Geneva: International Labour Organization.
26. Krueger A.B., Lindahl M. (2001). Education for Growth: Why and for Whom? Journal of Economic Literature, 39 (4), 1101-36.
27. Leuven E, Oosterbeek H. (2011). Overeducation and mismatch in the labor market. IZA Discussion Pape no. 5523
28. Little B. (2008). Graduate Development in European Employment — Issues and Contradictions', Education and Training, 50 (5), 379 -390.
29. Lucas R. (1988). On the Mechanics of Economic Development, Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3-42
30. Marelli E., Signorelli M. (2010). Productivity, employment and human capital in transition: a comparative approach, in E. Marelli & M. Signorelli (Eds.), Economic Growth and Structural Features of Transition, Palgrave Macmillan, chapter 4.
31. Mc Guinness S. (2006). Overeducation in the Labour Market. Journal of Economic Surveys. 20 (3), 387-418.
32. McGuinness S., Sloane P.J. (2010). Esiste overeducation? Un'analisi comparata, in AlmaLaurea, XIIRapporto sulla condizione occupazionale dei laureati. Il Mulino, Bologna.
33. Michaels G., Natraj A., van Reenen J. (2009). Has ICT Polarized Skill Demand? Evidence from Eleven Countries over 25 Years. London School of Economics, Centre for Economic Performance Working Paper, December
34. Mora J.-G. (ed.) (2008). The Labour Market ofEuropean Higher Education Graduates: Some Analytical Approaches. European Journal of Education, 42 (1) (special issue).
35. Nickell S. (2000). The distribution of wages and unemployment across skill groups, in: Landesmann M.A., Pichelmann K. (Eds.), Unemployment in Europe, MacMillan Press, 121-147.
36. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (2010). Education at a glance: OECD Education Indicators 2010. Paris: OECD.
37. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (2011). Higher Education in Regional and City Development: Lombardy, Italy. Paris: OECD.
38. O'Higgins N. (2012). This Time It's Different? Youth Labour Markets during 'The Great Recession. Comparative Economic Studies, 3.
39. Pastore F. (2011). Fuori dal tunnel, Giappichelli, Torino.
40. Pozzoli D. (2009). The Transition to Work for Italian University Graduates. Labour. 23: 1. 131-169.
41. Putnam R. (1993). Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
42. Quintini G., Martin J.P, Marti S. (2007). The Changing Nature of the School-to-Work Transition Process in OECD Countries. IZA Discussion Paper. 2582.
43. Scarpetta S., Sonnet A., Manfredi T. (2010). Rising youth unemployment during the crisis: how to prevent negative long-term consequences on a generation? OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper, No. 6, OECD, Paris, April.
44. Schomburg H. (2007). The Professional Success of Higher Education Graduates. European Journal of Education, 42 (1), 35-47.
45. Schomburg H., Teichler, U. (2006). Higher Education and Graduate Employment in Europe: Results of Graduates Surveys from 12 Countries. Dordrecht: Springer.
46. Schomburg H., Teichler U. (Eds.) (2011). Employability and Mobility of Bachelor Graduates in Europe. Key Results of the Bologna Process. Rotterdam: Sense Publishers.
47. Sciulli D., Signorelli M. (2011). University-to-work transitions: an empirical analysis on Perugia graduates. European Journal of Higher Education. 1 (1), 39-65.
48. Strauf S., Scherer R. (2008). Universities and their Contribution to Regional Development. Transformations in Business & Economics, 7 (1), 13.
49. Teichler U. (2007). Higher Education and the European Labour Market. In E. Froment, J. Kohler, L. Purser & L. Wilson (Eds.), EUA Bologna Handbook — Making Bologna Work. Berlin: Raabe, pp. 1-34.
50. Teichler U. (2009). Higher Education and the World of Work: Conceptual Framework, Comparative Perspectives, Empirical Findings. Rotterdam: Sense Publishers.
51. Teichler U. (2011). «Bologna — Motor or Stumbling Block for the Mobility and Employability of Graduates?». In Schomburg H. & Teichler U. (Eds.) Employability and Mobility of Bachelor Graduates in Europe. Key Results of the Bologna Process. Rotterdam: Sense Publishers.
Information about the authors
Marelli Enrico (Milan, Italy) — A.M. in Regional Science — Full Professor of Economic Policy, Department of Economics and Management, University of Brescia (via San Faustino 74/B, 25122 Brescia, BS — ITALY, e-mail: enrico.marelli@unibs.it).
Sciulli Dario (Pescara, Italy) — Ph.D. University of Tor Vergata, Rome — Assistant Professor of Economic Policy, Department of Economic Studies, University "G. d'Annunzio of Chieti-Pescara" (viale Pindaro 42, 65127 Pescara, PE — ITALY, e-mail: d.sci-ulli@unich.it).
Signorelli Marcello (Perugia, Italy) — Ph.D. University of Siena — Associate Professor of Economic Policy, Department of Economics, University of Perugia (via A. Pascoli 20, 06123 Perugia, PG — ITALY, e-mail: marcello.signorelli@unipg.it).
УДК 314.74
С. Н. Мищук
ОСОБЕННОСТИ МЕЖДУНАРОДНОЙ ТРУДОВОЙ МИГРАЦИИИ
ИЗ КИТАЯ В РОССИЮ1 (на примере Дальневосточного федерального округа)
В работе показана современная динамика международных миграционных процессов, в рамах которых происходит усиление роли стран Азиатско-Тихоокеанского региона, в том числе Китая. Дана оценка современного состояния и возможных сценариев развития миграционных потоков из КНР в РФ. На примере Еврейской автономной области показано, что привлечение трудовых мигрантов из Китая соответствует колебательному сценарию. Подробно проанализирована динамика международной трудовой миграции в южных субъектах Дальнего Востока РФ с учетом особенностей приграничного положения Дальнего Востока России и Северо-Восточных провинций Китая. На основе контент-анализа региональных СМИ дана оценка восприятия международной миграции населением южных субъектов Дальнего Востока России. Подчеркивается, что длительное привлечение трудовых иммигрантов привело к профессиональной деградации населения российских регионов, что проявляется на фоне снижения интереса китайских мигрантов к работе на территории России.
Ключевые слова: международная миграция, трудовая миграция, российско-китайские отношения, Дальний Восток России, Еврейская автономная область
В настоящее время миграция является глобальным явлением — изменения отдельных показателей в одной стране влекут за собой необходимость разработки мер по регулированию ситуации в других странах.
За последнюю четверть века произошли существенные изменения среди стран — лидеров по числу эмигрантов. В 1990 г. около
1 © С. Н. Мищук. Текст. 2014.
трети (33 %) международных мигрантов родились в Европе. Многие из этих «мигрантов» переехали еще в период существования Советского Союза и не считались мигрантами. Еще около трети (34 %) международных мигрантов в 1990 г. родились в странах Азиатско-Тихоокеанского региона, в том числе многие в индийском субконтиненте и странах высокой эмиграции, таких как Китай и Филиппины.