УДК 517.977.57: 512.816.7
L. A. Bordag
PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION IN THE CASE OF AN EXPONENTIAL UTILITY FUNCTION AND IN THE PRESENCE OF AN ILLIQUID ASSET
We study an optimization problem for a portfolio with a risk-free, a liquid, and an illiquid risky asset. The illiquid risky asset is sold in an exogenous random moment with a prescribed liquidation time distribution. We assume that the investor chooses an exponential utility function. Study of optimization problems with three assets including an illiquid asset leads to three-dimensional nonlinear Hamilton - Jacobi - Bellman (HJB) equations.
It is well known that the exponential utility function is connected with the HARA utility function through a limiting procedure if the parameter of the HARA utility function is going to infinity. We show that the optimization problem with the exponential utility function is not connected to the optimization problem with the HARA utility by the limiting procedure and we obtain essentially different results. We provide the Lie group analysis of the corresponding HJB equation.
For the main three-dimensional PDE with the exponential utility function, we obtain the complete set of the nonequivalent Lie group invariant reductions to two-dimensional PDEs according to an optimal system of subalgebras of the admitted Lie algebra. We prove that in just one case the invariant reduction is consistent with the boundary condition. This reduction represents a significant simplification of the original problem.
Изучена проблема оптимизации ивестиционного портфеля, включающего безрисковый актив, высоколиквидный и неликвидный активы. При этом неликвидный актив может быть продан в независимый случайный момент времени, и для него распределение времени ликвидации известно. Мы предполагаем, что инвестор предпочитает экспоненциальную функцию полезности. Изучение проблем оптимизации с тремя активами, включая неликвидный актив, приводит к трехмерным нелинейным уравнениям Гамильтона - Якоби - Беллмана (HJB).
Хорошо известно, что экспоненциальная функция полезности связана с гиперболической функцией полезности (гиперболическое неприятие абсолютного риска - HARA) посредством предельного перехода, при котором параметр гиперболической функции полезности стремится к бесконечности. Мы показываем, что проблема оптимизации инвестиционного портфеля с экспоненциальной функцией полезности не связана предельным переходом с проблемой оптимизации с гиперболической функцией полезности, и для нее получены существенно другие результаты.
Мы проводим теоретико-групповой анализ соответствующего уравнения Гамильтона - Якоби - Беллмана в случае использования экспоненциальной функции полезности. Для главного трехмерного уравнения в частных прозводных мы получаем полный набор неэквивалентных Ли групповых инвариантных редукций к двумерным уравнениям в частных производных согласно оптимальной системе подалгебр максимальной Ли алгебры, допускаемой этим уравнением. Мы доказываем,
73
© Бог^ Ь.Л., 2021
Вестник Балтийского федерального университета им. И. Канта. Сер.: Физико-математические и технические науки. 2021. № 1. С. 73-102.
что только в одном случае инвариантная редукция совместима с поставленным граничным условием. Эта редукция представляет собой существенное упрощение исходной задачи.
Keywords: portfolio optimization, illiquidity, Lie group analysis, invariant reductions
Ключевые слова: оптимизация портфеля ценных бумаг, неликвидность, Ли групповой анализ, инвариантные редукции
1. Introduction
74 We study an optimization problem for a portfolio with an illiquid, a
liquid risky, and a risk-free asset in the framework of continuous time. We suppose that the illiquid asset is sold in an exogenous random moment T with a prescribed liquidation time distribution.
Optimization problems, where the time-horizon is an exogenous random variable, may arise in different situations. The international financial crisis 2008 — 2009 initiated a change in the financial policy towards new, stronger regulations in many countries and also to some special insolvency regulations in EU countries. The actual corona crisis differs from the previous crisis 2008 — 2009 because of its strong global impact on economics. As a consequence, optimization problems with an exogenous random time of liquidation become right now very topical for most countries in Europe. Many small and medium-sized companies are forced now to liquidate their factories or houses because they cannot pay obligations in time. During this crisis, many investors changed also their risk tolerance towards a strong conservative one and the exponential utility function became more relevant than the HARA utility function. One can find many references on this topic in the short review [9] (which became especially actual right now), which is devoted to assessing risk tolerance in dependence of economic cycles as well as to a discussion of different parameter choices and forms of utility functions. This supports our assumption that during an economic crisis some investors will prefer to use instead of a HARA utility function a CARA utility function, for instance, an exponential utility function.
There are a large number of papers that generalize the famous Merton's model [16], for instance, some of them introducing a stochastic income in the Merton's classical portfolio as in [8], and others are devoted to the classical optimal investment problem with a random endowment such as works [7; 10]. The main new feature in our problem is that the portfolio includes an illiquid asset with a prescribed liquidation time distribution. For the first time, the optimization problem in this form with the HARA utility function was introduced in the paper [4] and later studied in papers [2; 3; 5]. If the illiquid asset in the portfolio is a real estate, a factory, a plant, or store then you can sell it as a whole only. It is a typical situation with the selling of houses, small factories, or shops that you know the market situation and a typical liquidation time distribution. For instance, in a seller market, the liquidation time distribution will be rather an exponential distribution. If it is the buyer market then it will be closer to a Weibull distribution. We study in this paper both liquidation time distributions as special cases.
The influence of the risk tolerance preferred by the investor on the solution of an optimization problem was studied before for different portfolio settings with and without an illiquid asset. We review here some results which are relevant for the selection of the utility function.
In the paper [18], the authors started with the classical Merton's optimization problem used in [15; 16]. The portfolio contains one liquid risky asset and a risk-free money market account. The trading takes place within a fixed finite time horizon. The authors explore the question of risk management under different risk preferences of the investor. They study the optimal wealth process and the portfolio process across different utilities and provide transformations between two such processes corresponding to two arbitrary utilities. It is possible to find a deterministic transformation using the local absolute risk tolerance function associated with the corresponding utility function. This transformation is defined by a solution of a linear heat equation with the risk tolerance function as a coefficient by the second spatial derivative. Because of the classical problem features, it is possible to study the influence of the chosen utility and the risk tolerance on the wealth process and the different characteristics of the optimal portfolio in detail. The authors prove that the curvature of the risk tolerance function of the preferred utility function plays the main role. Certainly, we cannot expect such tractability from an optimization problem with an illiquid asset, but we can use this model as a benchmark for the case if the volume of the illiquid position of the studied portfolio vanishes.
The dependence of optimal liquidation strategies from the risk aversion of investors was studied in [23]. The authors consider the infinite time horizon in the optimal portfolio liquidation problem and use a stochastic control approach. In this model, a large investor trades one risky and one risk-free asset. Thereby due to insufficient liquidity of the risky asset the investor's trading rate moves the market price for the risky asset. The authors obtain nonlinear parabolic partial differential equations (PDEs) for the value function and the optimal strategy. They have to determine the adaptive trading strategy that maximizes the expected utility of the proceeds of a large asset sale. Withal authors studied the financial influence of different types of investor's utility functions. They found that the optimal strategy is aggressive or passive in-the-money in dependence of the investor's risk tolerance, i. e. if the utility function displays increasing or decreasing risk aversion. The authors proved that such strategies are rational for investors with different absolute risk aversion profiles.
Another approach to a liquidation problem of an illiquid asset is provided in paper [17]. It is devoted to the problem of how efficiently liquidate large assets positions up to an exogenous fixed terminal time. The author supposes that the investor prefers the exponential utility function and seeks to maximize the expected utility of the terminal value of his wealth. The portfolio contains an illiquid asset called a primary risky asset, a liquid asset that is imperfectly correlated with the primary asset and is called a proxy risky asset as well as a riskless money market account that
75
pays zero interest rate. In practice, the investor tries to reduce the price impact by trading a large number of assets and to hedge market risk of the liquidated portfolio. As a common strategy one chooses splitting of the given order into smaller pieces and to trade these pieces sequentially over time. The author can find optimal strategies explicitly and study their properties. The strategies depend on time and parameters of the model only and are solutions of a linear ordinary differential equation (ODE) of the second order. The author proves that this case is a generalization of the original Merton's model studied in [15; 16]. He also noticed that the explicit and simple results for optimal strategies were possible to obtain just by using finite terminal time and because of the investor used the exponential utility function. A more realistic setting, for instance, where the investor receives multiply orders at random times or the liquidation time is not fixed in the beginning leads to an essential more complicated model. In comparison to our case, the illiquid asset in [17] does not pay any dividends and the investor can also split the illiquid asset and sell them piece by piece as well as the investor has no consumption during the lifetime of the portfolio.
Study of optimization problems with three assets including an illiquid asset leads to three-dimensional nonlinear Hamilton — Jacobi — Bellman (HJB) equations. The corresponding nonlinear three-dimensional PDEs include a lot of parameters describing the behavior of assets and are challenging for analytical and numerical methods. To simplify the investigated problem one tries to find an inner symmetry of such an equation and reduce the number of independent variables at least to two or if possible to one. Usually, lower-dimensional problems are better studied and are, therefore, easier to handle. We use in this paper the powerful method of Lie group analysis. This method is very well known for more than 100 years. It is very often used in the area of mathematical physics or to study nonlinear diffusion in porous media where similar nonlinear heat equations arise (see [24—26]). Over the past 20 years this method also used in financial mathematics [1]. Nearly all known explicit solutions to ODEs or PDEs were found or can be found algorithmically (i. e. without guessing) by this method. This method is up to now the most appropriate method to find algorithmically substitutions to reduce a higher-dimensional PDE to a lower-dimensional one or even to an ODE.
The Lie algebraic structure of the corresponding HJB equation is one of the two main results of this paper. The Lie algebraic structure of the HJB equation reveals important structural properties of the considered equation. For instance, for the linear Black-Scholes equation, the corresponding Lie algebraic structure gives rise to famous substitutions which reduce it to the heat equation or it allowed to obtain the fundamental solution and the explicit formulas for European Call or Put. For a nonlinear equation like that studied here, we cannot get any fundamental solution but we can obtain reductions of the high-dimensional HJB equation to simpler ones. We study the complete set of all possible reductions and describe the unique reduction
to a two-dimensional PDE which satisfies the boundary conditions. We present also the explicit form of the corresponding investment-consumption strategies in invariant variables. This reduction also means that for all further investigation it is sufficient to use the two-dimensional PDE instead of the three-dimensional main HJB equation.
Our paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we introduce the economic problem features in detail. We provide there a theorem stating that the HJB equation with a HARA utility function possesses a unique viscosity solution which was earlier proved in [4]. This Theorem will be now modified for the case of an exponential utility function. In Section 3 we provide the Lie group analyses of the optimization problems with a general liquidation time distribution and different utility functions. We prove that the cases of a HARA utility and an exponential utility are completely different. The usual limiting procedure between the HARA and exponential utility functions gives us wrong results for the corresponding Lie algebraic structures. In Section 4, for the optimization problem with the exponential utility function, we chose an optimal system of subalgebras of the admitted Lie algebra and provide the complete set of all invariant reductions of the corresponding three-dimensional PDE. Because this is an essential step, the complete prove with all details is given and the meaning of each reduction is explained. In each case, we prove if the invariant substitutions are compatible with the boundary condition. In Section 5 we discuss the connection between different results and see that the radical change of the investment-consumption strategies is connected with the chosen exponential utility function.
2. Economical setting
We study an optimization problem for a portfolio in the framework of continuous time. An investor has a portfolio with three assets: an illiquid, a liquid risky, and a risk-free asset. The investor has an illiquid asset that has some paper value and can not be sold until some moment T that is random with a prescribed liquidation time distribution. The investor tries to maximize her average consumption investing into a liquid risky asset that is partly correlated with the illiquid one. The investor is free to choose a utility function in correspondence with her risk tolerance. In our previous papers [3—5] we assumed that the investor chooses a hyperbolic absolute risk aversion (HARA) utility function or a logarithmic (LOG) utility function as a special case of the HARA utility. Now we suppose that the investor has a quite different risk tolerance as before and chooses an exponential utility function. We notice that a risk tolerance R(c) of an investor is defined as
R(c) = - U (c) for any utility function U(c), c e [0, x). For the HARA utility U (c)
function, the risk tolerance R(c) is a linear function of c and for the exponential utility function, it is a constant.
77
78
Because the form of utility functions define the form of HJB equations and the limiting procedures connecting the HARA utility with the loga-rithmical and exponential utility functions play an important role in this paper we describe these relations in more detail. In the previous papers [2—5] we used the HARA and LOG utility functions and studied the connection between both optimization problems. We used the HARA utility function in the form
tHARA/S _ 1 y
U Г" (c ) = -
1 -У
-1
, 0< У<1. (1)
It is easy to see that as y ^ 0 then the HARA utility function written as (1) tends to the LOG utility
UHARA (cU ^ ULOG (c) = ln c. (2)
In common literature is often noticed that we obtain an exponential utility function as a limit case of a HARA utility function by y . This assertion is correct just if the HARA utility function takes a special form, for instance, for the HARA utility in the form (1) it is not the case. It is easy to prove that if we take the HARA utility in the form
U^RA (c) = ^-4 — +11 , 0< y <1, a >0, (3)
y {1-y J
then we obtain by the limiting procedure an exponential utility function
UHARA (c UEXP (c ) = -e ~ac. (4)
It is a so-called exponential utility function (denoted as EXP). The most common form of the exponential utility function is
UEXPp(c) = i(1 -e-^), a >0. (5)
a
We call it a positive exponential utility function (and denote it as EXPp). Both (4) and (5) utility functions differ just by an additive and a
1
multiplicative constant —. We will prove later that both optimization
a
problems, with EXP and EXPp utility functions are equivalent.
The forms UHARA and U2HARA of the HARA utility function are often used and from an economical point of view, both of them have properties of a HARA type utility function. From the analytical point of view, the HARA utility functions U1HARA and U2HARA are different.
In the case of UHARA, we obtain by limiting transition y ^ 0 a LOG utility function (2). As we mentioned before the risk tolerance, in this case, is equal to
R1(c ) = - ^(£1 = -^, (6)
1 U "(c) 1 -y
У
and by y ^ 0 we obtain RLOG (c) = c as it to expect. But we get neither a finite limit by y ^x of the function U]IIARA(c) nor a relevant value for the risk aversion R7(c) in this case.
In the second case for the utility function U2HARA (3), we obtain for the risk tolerance the expression
R2(c ) = a^y = 7^" +1 ■ (7)
a(1 - y) 1 - y a
Here U2HARA tends by the limiting transition y ^x to the EXP utility function (4) and the risk tolerance takes a constant value R2(c) = a-1 as it is to expect in the case of an exponential utility function. But here in contradiction to the first case of U 1'ARA, we cannot obtain any meaningful expression by the limiting procedure y ^ 0, it means we do not obtain a transition to the LOG utility function.
In other words to study the connection between two optimization problems with a HARA utility function and with a logarithmic utility function we should use the HARA utility for instance in the form UHARA (c) to be able to provide the limiting procedure y ^ 0 in all formulas. For the study the connection between two optimization problems with a HARA utility and with an exponential utility we should use another form of the HARA utility, for instance, of type U 2HARA (c) to be able to make the limiting transition for y^x in corresponding formulas.
Because of the relation (4) to correct comparison of the results for the optimization problem with the HARA utility function U 2HARA (c) with the results for an optimization problem with an exponential utility function we need to study first the optimization problem with the exponential utility function UEXP(c). The optimization problems with exponential utility functions (4), (5) describe economically equivalent situations. There exist one-to-one analytical substitution which provides the equivalence relation between two of these optimization problems which we show explicitly later in Section 3.2.
From (6) and (7) follows that the functions R7(c), R2(c), RLOG (c) are linear functions of c . It means also that the absolute risk tolerance is increasing or decreasing with the consumption c in these cases. For an exponential utility function the risk tolerance is a constant. In other words, all the time the absolute risk tolerance stays unaltered in the framework of these optimization problems.
We see that even though both the LOG and EXP utility functions can be regarded as a limit case of the HARA utility function they describe quite different economical situations: in the first case, the risk tolerance changes with the consumption c and in the case of the EXP utility function the risk tolerance do not depend on the level of the consumption at all.
It means that now the investor has a constant risk tolerance. Maybe it explains that both optimization problems studied before and presented now have quite different analytic and Lie algebraic structures as we show it later.
79
2.1. Formulation of the optimization problem
We introduce a filtered probability space (Q, F, F, P), where F = (Ft )t a0 is the natural filtration, generated by two independent standard Brownian motions W1 and W2, and verifying usual properties: it is completed and right continuous (see [12]).
The liquidation time T of the portfolio is a non-negative random variable on the same probability space (Q, F, P), and this allows us to introduce an additional source of uncertainty that is not connected to the randomness of the financial market. We suppose that the cumulative distribution function ® of the random variable T is known and related to the law PT of T in the usual way: Vt e M, ®(t) = PT (] - ro, t]).
The probability density function of the liquidation time distribution is denoted by ^(t), whereas ®(t) denotes the survival function, also known as a reliability function, ®(t) = 1 - ®(t). We skip here the explicit notion of the possible parameters of the distribution to make the formulas shorter.
In dependence on the rate of illiquidity, the liquidation time distribution can take different forms. Typically one uses the simplest one parameter exponential distribution with the reliability function ®(t) = e-Kt, where k is the parameter of the distribution or a more advanced Weibull distribution with ®(t) = e-(t/2) with two parameters, 2 and k . We will take these two distributions as examples in our investigation. We notice that the exponential distribution is a special case of the Weibull distribution by k = 1 and k = 1 / 2 .
Assumptions and constrains.
We suppose that a utility function U(-) satisfies the following conditions:
lim®(t)E[U(ct)] = 0, ®(t) - e-Kt, k > 0 or faster as t ^<x>. (8)
For a variable c e [0, ro) the function U(c) is strictly increasing, concave and twice differentiable in c, further on
U(c) < M(1 + cf, 0< y <1, M >0, (9)
and either limU '(c) = +ro, limU'(c) = 0, (10)
c ^0 c—>+ro
or U' (c)| = const. > 0, limU'(c) = 0. (11)
c=0 c—+ro
The investor's portfolio includes a risk-free bond Bt, a risky asset St and a non-traded asset Ht that generates stochastic income, i.e. dividends or costs of maintaining the asset. The risk-free bank account Bt , with the interest rate r , follows
dBt = rBtdt, t < T, (12)
where r is constant. The lower case index t denotes the spot value of the asset at the moment t.
The stock price St follows the geometrical Brownian motion
dSt = St(adt + adW]),i < T, (13)
with the continuously compounded rate of return a > r and the standard deviation a . The illiquid asset Ht, that can not be traded up to the time T and its paper value is correlated with the stock price and is governed by
H- = (u -8)dt + r[pdW] +V 1-p2 dWt2j,t < T, (14)
where ju is the expected rate of return of the risky illiquid asset, (W/, Wt2) are two independent standard Brownian motions, 8 is the rate of dividend paid by the illiquid asset, r is the standard deviation of the rate of return, and p e (-1,1) is the correlation coefficient between the stock index and the illiquid risky asset. The parameters u, 8, /, P are all assumed to be constant.
The randomly distributed time T is an exogenous time and it does not depend on the Brownian motions (W/, Wt2) as we mentioned before.
Given the filtration F, we assume that the consumption process (ct )t a0 is an element of the space £+ of non-negative F -progressively measurable
processes such that E |jQcsds j < x, t e [0, T].
All the income is derived from the capital gains and the investor must be solvent. In other words, the liquid wealth process (Ls )t<s<T must cover the consumption stream. The wealth process (Ls )t<s<T is the sum of cash holdings in bonds, stocks and random dividends from the non-traded asset minus the consumption stream, i. e. it must satisfy the balance equation
dLs =(rLs + 8Hs +xs (a-r)-cs )ds +xsadWs\ t < s < T . (15)
The set of admissible policies (^t, ct )ta0 is standard and consists of allocation-consumption strategies such that: (ct )t a0 belongs to £+; (^t )t a0 is
rs 2
F -progressively measurable and Jt (nT)dr< x a. s. for any t < s < T; (Ls )t<s<T, defined by the stochastic differential equation (15) and initial conditions Lt = l > 0,Ht = h >0 a.e. The consumption stream (ct )ta0 is admissible if and only if it is positive and if there exists a strategy that finances it. We assume that the investor consumes at rate (ct )t a0 from the liquid wealth and the allocation-consumption plan (^t, ct )ta0 consists of the allocation of the portfolio with the cash amount (^t )t a0 invested in stocks, the consumption stream (ct )t a0 and the rest of the capital kept in bonds.
81
82
Remark 1. Further on we sometimes omit the dependence on t in some of the equations for the sake of clarity of the formulas.
The investor wants to maximize the overall utility consumed up to the random time of liquidation T , given by
U (ct ):= E
{^(t )U(ct )dt
(16)
as it was shown in [4]. It means we work with the problem (16) that corresponds to the value function V(l, h, t ), which is defined as
V (l, h, t ) = maxE
(wt ,ct)
j™®(s)U(cs )ds | Lt = l, Ht = h, l, h > 0
(17)
where l could be regarded as initial capital and h as a paper value of the illiquid asset. The value function V (l, h, t ) satisfies the HJB equation
Vt (l, h, t )+h2 Vh (l, h, t) + (rl + Sh)Vl (l, h, t ) + (/u-S)hVk (l, h, t ) + maxGk]+maxH[c ] = 0, (18)
n c>0
GM = 2 va (l, h, t)n2a2 + Vhl (l, h, t)7/nrh + n(a-r )Vl (l, h, t), (19)
H[c ] = -cV, (l, h, t) + ®(t)U(c), (20)
with the boundary condition
V(l, h, t) ^ 0, as t ^«5. (21)
In [4; 5] the authors have already demonstrated that the formulated problem has a unique solution under certain conditions. Namely, the following theorem was proved
Theorem 1 [4]. There exists a unique viscosity solution of the corresponding HJB equation (17) — (21) if the conditions (8), (9), and (10) are fulfilled.
In this paper, we restrict ourselves to the case of an exponential utility function that satisfies three first conditions (8), (9) of Theorem 1 by definition. We checked the proof of the theorem in [4] and see that the Inada condition (10) can be replaced by the condition (11) and the existence and uniqueness of the viscosity solution of HJB equation is still guaranteed.
Further, we will use instead of the fourth condition in Theorem 1 the condition (11) which will be satisfied by an exponential utility function. It means that there exists a unique viscosity solution to the HJB equation (17) — (21) with an exponential utility function.
Now we can adjust and reformulate Lemma proved in [4] about the properties of the value function as follows
Lemma 1. Under the conditions (8), (9) and the condition (11) the value function V(t, l, h) (17) has the following properties:
(i) V(l, h, t) is concave and non-decreasing in l and in h,
(ii) V(l, h, t) is strictly increasing in l,
(iii) V(l, h, t) is strictly decreasing in t starting from some point,
(iv) 0 < V(l, h, t) < O(| l \r + | h \r) uniformly in t.
In the next sections, we will first study three-dimensional PDE which we obtain from the HJB equation after formal maximization, then we will try to simplify this three-dimensional PDE as far as possible using its internal algebraic structure. The properties of the value function listed in Lemma 1 we will use to define the reduction which keeps all properties of the original optimization problem. It follows that if one can find a solution to the reduced equation it will be also the unique viscosity solution of the optimization problem.
83
3. Lie group analyses of the optimization problem with a general liquidation time distribution and an exponential utility function
First, we study the case of an optimization problem with the EXP utility function (4). As usual, we provide a formal maximization of (19) and (20) for the chosen utility function in the HJB equation (18) and get a three-dimensional nonlinear PDE.
The HJB equation (18) after the formal maximization procedure will take the form
Vt (l, h, t)+-I/h 2Vh (l, h, t) + (rl + 8h )Vl (l, h, t) + (u - 8)hVh (l, h, t)
- (a - r )2 V2 (l, h, t) + 2(a - r )/phV, (l, h, t )Vh (l, h, t) + r2p2a2 h2Vlh 2 (l, h, t)
2a2Vu (l, h, t)
+1 Vt (l, h, t) ln Vt (l, h, t) -1 (l + ln ®(i) )Vr (l, h, t) - — V (l, h, t) = 0, (22)
a av ' a
V ^ 0, t ^ x.
Here the investment 7r(l, h, t) and consumption c(l, h, t) strategies look as follows in terms of the value function V(l, h, t)
h, t)= -rpahVl>>(l, ht) +(a-r )Vl(l,h,t), (23)
a2Vn (l, h, t)
1
c(l, h, t ) = -ln
a
®(t)
a^ (l, h, t)
(24)
Equation (22) is a nonlinear three-dimensional PDE with the three independent variables l, h, t. Such equations are demanding by study with analytical or numerical methods. The Lie group analysis of a nonlinear PDE is a proper tool to obtain the Lie algebra admitted by this equation. Using the generators of this symmetry algebra one can reduce the dimension of the equation (22) and make a problem better tractable.
Roughly speaking to obtain internal Lie algebraic structure of a differential equation on any function V (l, h, t) we present this equation as an algebraic equation, for instance like A(l,h,t,V,Vl,Vh,Vt,Va,Vlh,Vhh) = 0 in some special space called the jet bundle. This space is denoted by j(n), where n is the order of the highest derivative in the differential equation. All derivatives will be now considered as new dependent variables. Thereafter we study the properties of the solution manifold of this equation, which is now a surface in the jet bundle j(n). We take a generator U of a point transformation in the corresponding jet bundle and act on the solution 84 manifold to define invariant subspaces. One obtains a large system of partial -——I differential equations on the coefficients of the generator U. Usually, this system does not have any nontrivial solution at all, and correspondingly the studied differential equation does not admit any symmetry. In seldom cases, one gets nontrivial generators of the point transformations admitted by the equation. The symmetry properties will then used to simplify the studied equation and one obtains a so-called reduced equation. In detail, one can find the description of this method in [11; 19], or in [1] where a short and comprehensive introduction in this method is given as well as applications to other PDEs arising in financial mathematics.
Here we formulate the main theorem of Lie group analysis for the optimization problem with the EXP utility function.
Theorem 2. The HJB equation (22) with the EXP utility function (4) and with a general liquidation time distribution ®(T) admits the four-dimensional Lie algebra Le4xp spanned by generators Ut, U2, U3, U4, i. e. LE4XP =< U1, U2, U3, U4>, where
1 3 3 3
U=—V—, U2=—, (25)
1 ar 3l 3V 2 3V
U3=-£ le-"d ®«)f+ts , U'=f
with following nontrivial commutation relations
[ Uj, U2] = U2, [U3, U 4 ] = U4, (26)
i.e. Le4xp is of the type A2 © A2 after the classification provided in [22]. Except for the finite-dimensional Lie algebra LE4XP (25), the equation (22)
3
admits also an infinite-dimensional algebra Lm =< ^(h, t)—> where the
™ 3V
function i//(h, t) is any solution of the linear parabolic PDE
Wt (h, t)+h2^hH (h, t) + (m- S)h¥h (h, t) = 0. (27)
Remark 2. First the formulation of this theorem was presented in [6].
Proof. As it shown in [19], [11] or [1] we introduce the second jet bundle j(2) and present the equation (22) in the form A(l, h, t, V, Vl ,Vh ,Vt, Vll, Vlh, Vhh) = 0 as a function of these variables in the jet bundle j(2). We look for generators of the admitted Lie algebra in the form
U = £ (l, h, t, V)— + £(l, h, t, V )■— + £(l, h, t, V) — + r (l, h, t, V)—, (28)
blW ' ' dl 2W oh 3W dt lW dV
where the functions £,£,£,/ can be found using the overdetermined system of determining equations
U(2)A(l, h, t, V, Vl, Vh, Vt, Vll, Vm, Vhh) Ia=0 = 0, (29)
where U(2) is the second prolongation of U in j(2). We look at the action of U(2) on A(l, h, t ,V ,Vl ,Vh ,Vt ,Va ,VK ,Vlh ,Vhh) located on its solution subvariety A = 0 and obtain an overdetermined system of PDEs on the functions £, £, £, and / from (28). This system has 130 PDEs on the functions £,£,£,/. Most of them are trivial and lead to the following conditions on the functions
(£ )h = 0, (£ )v = 0, (£ ) l = 0, (£ )l = £u (t),
(££)l =0,(££)v =0,
(£b)i =0, (£)h =0, (£,)v =0, (/l )l = 0, (/l )VV = 0, (/l )V = /11(h, t).
Consequently, the unknown functions in (28) have the following structure
£(l, h, t, V) = £ (t)l + £12 (t), £(l, h, t, V) = £2 (h, t), £(l, h, t, V) = £3 (t),
/ (l, h, t, V) = / (h, t )V + r12 (h, t). (30)
Here £u(t),£12(t),£2(t, h),£3(t),/71(t, h), and r12(t, h) are some functions which will be defined later. To find these unknown functions we should have a closer look at the nontrivial equations of the obtained system, that are
left. After all simplifications, we get the system of seven PDEs
r2 h 2
/it ^^^rihh + (u - 8)hrih = 0, (31)
£ -£l =0,
1
(u-8)(#2 - h#2h + h£t) -^r2h2£hh +r2h2/iih = 0, h£t + 2(£ - h£h) = 0,
85
86
1 1 1 ®t
/ii + r£ - - £ + £ ---r £ =0, a a a ®
(a- r )£3t + 2rPhrUh =0,
(a - r)(£ - h£2h + h£t) + rP°2h2/iih =
o 1 o2 o
We introduce the differential operator L = —i—/h2—t + (j-^)h—
dt 2 Oh Oh
using this operator we can rewrite the first equation in the above system as
conditions on the functions r11( h, t) and r12( h, t) which appears in the last
equation of (30) correspondingly as L/11( h, t ) = 0 and L/12( h, t ) = 0. Other
equations in the above system do not contain the function /12 (h, t) at all. If
we now denote r12 (h, t) = ^(h, t) then we see that we proved the last
statement of the theorem, see (27).
Solving the system (31) for an arbitrary function ®(t) we obtain
£ = cu eTt +/--£-ert fe-rt ?tdt, £2 = 0, ar a J ®
£3 - const., r =r11V + r122 + w(h, t), c11, r71, r122 - const. (32)
The equations (32) contain four arbitrary constants £, c71, /, r122 and a function r12 (h, t) = h, t) which is an arbitrary solution of L y/(h, t) = 0 . Formulas (32) define four generators of the finite-dimensional Lie algebra LEiXP (25) and the infinitely dimensional algebra La (27) as it was described in Theorem 2.
Remark 3. The found four-dimensional Lie algebra describes the symmetry property of the equation (22) for any function ®(t). In [4; 5] we have proved the theorem for existence and uniqueness of the solution of HJB equation for a liquidation time distribution for which ®(t) ~ e-Kt or faster as t , therefore we will regard this type of the distribution studying the analytical properties of the equation further on.
First, we explain the meaning of some generators of the Lie algebra
o
listed in Theorem 2. We start with the second generator U2 = —. It means
2 oV
that the original value function V (l, h, t) which is a solution of the equation (22), can be shifted on any constant and still be a solution of the same equation. Neither allocation tt nor consumption function c will change their values because they also depend only on the derivatives of the value function. In some sense, it is a trivial symmetry, since the equation (22) contains just the derivatives of V (l, h, t) so we certainly can add a constant to this function and it still will be a solution of the equation. Following this symmetry does not give a rise to any reductions of the studied three-
dimensional PDE and this symmetry does not satisfy the boundary condition V(l, h, t) ^ 0, t because of that, it is not interesting by solving of the possed optimization problem.
d
The fourth generator U 4 = ert — means that the value of the indepen-
dl
dent variable l can be shifted on the arbitrary value dert, i.e. the shift l ^ l + der, d - const. leaves the solution unaltered. From an economical point of view, it means that the absolute value of the initial capital is not important for this problem. We can arbitrarily shift the initial liquidity l on a bank account d, d >0 or credit d, d <0 yet l + der should be positive in the initial time moment. The value function V(l, h, t) as a solution to the equation (22) and the allocation-consumption strategy (n, c ) will be unaltered. This symmetry is trivial and it does not provide any reductions of the original three-dimensional PDE.
d
We also get the infinitely dimensional algebra Lœ =< y/(h, t)— > where
™ dV
the function i//(h, t ) is any solution of the linear PDE
1
W + 2r>1 h 2^hh + (M-S)hWh =0, see Theorem 2. It has a special meaning - we can add any solution y/(h, t ) of this equation to the value function V (l, h, t ) without any changes of the allocation-consumption strategy (n, c ). From an economical point of view, it means that the additional use of some financial instrument which is the 1
solution of i//t + "jr2 h 2Whh + (M-d)hWh =0 do not change the investment-allocation strategies in this optimization problem. The boundary condition V(l, h, t) ^ 0, t leads to the following boundary condition on the solution of this equation w(h, t) ^ 0, t . It means it is a financial instrument which value is defined just by the paper value of the illiquid asset and time only, can not change the allocation-consumption strategy (n,c). We notice also that after the substitution h = ex, t = -2r/r2,
(V-8--r2)/r2 -(p-S-¿r2)2r/r4
i//(t, h) = h 2 e 2 v(z, x) we obtain on the function v(z, x) the parabolic equation of the type vt = vxx, which is well studied. The solution methods as well as the fundamental solution of this equation are well known.
3.1. Relation between two optimization problems: one with the HARA and one with the EXP utility function
87
In our previous papers, we studied the optimization problem with an illiquid asset in the case if the investor used the HARA utility function (1) or the logarithmic utility function (2). It is well known that both problems are
88
connected by limiting procedure if - ^ 0. In the previous paper [3] we proved that also analytic and Lie algebraic structures of both optimization problems also connected with the same limiting procedure.
We noticed before that the EXP utility function is connected to the HARA utility function UHARA (c) with the limiting procedure by - , see (4).
It means also that we cannot use directly the results of the Lie group analysis obtained in previous works [2; 3] to compare the admitted Lie algebras for the optimization problem with the HARA utility function in the form U -IARA (c) with the results in this work for an optimization problem with an exponential utility function. Because of that, we should recalculate the results of the Lie group analysis for the new form of the HARA utility function. We remember that we first provide the formal maximization in the HJB equation (18) and correspondingly to the chosen utility function we obtain a three-dimensional PDE. In our previous works [2; 3] we used the utility function U-HARA(c) in the form (1). Now if we insert in the HJB equation (18) the HARA utility function UHARA (3) then we obtain the PDE in the form
Vt (t, l, h)+-ly h 2Vhh (t, l, h)+(rl + Sh )V (t, l, h)+(m~ S)hVh (t, l, h)
_ (a - r )2 V2 (t, l, h) + 2(a - r )rtphVl (t, l, h)Vh (t, l, h) + rfp2^ h2Vh 2 (t, l, h)
2a2Vu (t, l, h)
(1 -y)2— ^ _y 1 -y
+S-J^. o(t)1-yVl (t, l, h)1-y--y-Vt (t, l, h) = 0, 0. (33)
y a
The previous equation and (33) differ analytically in the last terms, from an economical point of view they describe equivalent optimization problems. The Lie group analysis of the previous equation was provided in [3]. We can use the same method and find the admitted Lie group for the equation (33) or use a substitution. Indeed if we take the substitutions
I = l -h = h, t = t, V = V +f®(t)dt (34)
ar - J
then the HJB equation in [3] on the function V (l, h, i) will be replaced by the equation (33) on the value function V (l, h, t).
We formulate the results of the Lie group analysis in the following theorem
Theorem 3. The equation (33) admits the three-dimensional Lie algebra L™™2 spanned by generators L^™1 =< U1, U2, U3 >, where
U1=A, u2= 1, U3= | l++ + , (35)
1 dV 2 dl 3 I ar )dl dh dV
for any liquidation time distribution. Moreover, if and only if the liquidation time distribution has the exponential form, i.e. ®(t ) = de -Kt, where d,K are constants
the studied equation admits a four-dimensional Lie algebra LfARA2 with an additional generator
U 4= — -Kv—, (36)
4 dt dV
i. e. LHfARA2 =< Uj, U2, U3, U4 >.
Except for the finite-dimensional Lie algebras (35) and (36) correspondingly
d
equation (33) admits also an infinite-dimensional algebra Lx =< y/(h, t) > where the function y( h, t) is any solution of the linear PDE
Wt (h, t)+2l2 h2^hh (h, t) + (M- S)h¥h (h, t) = 0. (37)
The Lie algebra LfARA2 has the following non-zero commutator relations
[Uj, U3 ] = yUj, [U2, U3 ] = U2. (38)
The Lie algebra LfARA2 has the following non-zero commutator relations [Uj, U3 ] = yUj, [Uj, U4 ] = -kU1,
[U2, U3 ] = U2, [U2, U4 ] = -rU2. (39)
We will not provide the proof of Theorem 3 because it is quite similar to the proof of the previous Theorem 3 for the equation (22).
It is easy to see that both algebras LfARAl presented in [3] and LfARA2 have the same commutation relations (39) and are isomorph. We prove that the admitted Lie algebras are also similar because of the substitution (34). It means that the optimization problems with the utility functions UfARA and with UfARA are equivalent not only from an economical and an analytical but also from the Lie algebraic point of view.
Now we have a correct form of generators of the Lie algebra to study a limiting procedure by y . Indeed using the properties of the generators of the Lie algebra we obtain from (35)
u; =—, U™ = ert —, Ur =— —-V—. (40)
1 —V 2 5/ 3 ar dl dV
Now we compare this Lie algebraic structure with the described in
Theorem 2. First, we see that both three-dimensional PDEs have the same
—
infinite-dimensional algebra L; =< y/(h, t)— >. Then we compare the finite —
dV
89
dimensional algebra (40) with (25) and see that the finite-dimensional algebras in these cases are essentially different. In the case of the U HARA (c) utility function and a general liquidation time distribution, we have after limiting transition - ^x the three-dimensional algebra (40) and in the case of the EXP utility function, we got the four-dimensional algebra (25). These algebras do not connect with the limiting procedure by - ^x as well as both three-dimensional PDEs (33) and (22) are not connected with this limiting procedure. Also the HJB problems have different analytical structures. Other sides it is easy to see that all three generators (40) coincide with the three of the four generators (25). Lie algebra (25) is in some way extension of the Lie algebra (40). It means that using the exponential utility function makes the corresponding optimization problem smoother from the Lie algebraic point of view.
We see that by limiting procedure - ^x neither the analytic nor the Lie algebraic structure of the optimization problem will be preserved. If in the previous cases [3] of the HARA and LOG utility functions it was sufficient to study the case of the HARA utility and then just take a limit by - ^ 0 to obtain the corresponding results for the optimization problem with LOG utility function now we should study the optimization problem with the exponential utility function in own rights step-by-step independently from the case of the HARA utility function.
3.2. Relation between two optimization problems correspondingly one with the EXP and one with the EXPp utility function
The EXPp utility function (5) is very close to the EXP function (4), the functions are connected by an affine transformation. Analogously to the previous chapter we can formulate and prove the main theorem of the Lie group analysis for the HJB optimization problem with the positive exponential utility function. We skip this part because we are able to provide an analytical substitution which connect both problems. It is easy to see that if we make following transformations of the variables l, h, t,V in equation (22)
l = l +—, h = h, t = t, (41)
ar
V(l, h, t) = V(l, h, t) + i j®(f )dt,
then the final equation in variables l, h, i, V coincide with HJB equation with the EXPp utility function. Because of the substitution (41) is an invertible analytical one-to-one substitution we have to do with two identical optimization problems. The analytical and the Lie algebraic structures of the optimization problems with the EXP and EXPp utility functions are equivalent and it is enough to study one of these problems in detail.
4. Optimal system of subalgebras of L4 and related invariant reductions of the corresponding three-dimensional PDE
To find all reductions and in this way to find all classes of the none-quivalent group invariant solutions of a differential equation Ovsiannikov in [20] has introduced the idea of an optimal system of subalgebras for a given symmetry algebra of the differential equation. This idea is now widely used for PDEs and systems of ODEs arising in different areas of sciences [13; 14; 21].
Now we will study a complete set of possible reductions of the three-dimensional PDE (22) to two-dimensional PDEs. For this purpose, we need an optimal system of subalgebras of LE4XP . As before in [3] we use an optimal system developed in [22] for the real four-dimensional Lie algebras of this type. To make the comparison of the results transparent we introduce in this Section the same notations for the generators of LE4XP as in [3; 22].
On the basis (25) of LE4XP, there are only two non-zero commutation relations (26). If we introduce notations like in the paper [22], i.e. we denote U = ei where i = 1,.. ,4 then we can rewrite the relations (26) as
[ei , e2 ]= e2 , [e3,e4] = e 4. (42)
Now we can see that LEXP corresponds to the algebras of the type A2 © A2 in the classification of [22] where also optimal systems of subalgebras for all real three and four-dimensional solvable Lie algebras are provided. The corresponding system of optimal subalgebras of LE4XP is listed in Table.
The optimal system of one-, two- and three- dimensional subalgebras of LEXP , where m is a parameter such that —<x < m < <x
91
Dimension of the subalgebra System of optimal subalgebras of algebra LEXP
1 h1 =< e2 >, h2 =< e3 >, h3 =< e4 >, h4 =< e1 + coe3 >, h5 =< e1 + e4 >, h6 =< e2 + e4 >, h7 =< e2 + e3 >
2 h8 =< e1, e3 >, h9 =< e1, e4 >, h10 =< e2 , e3 > h11 =< e2 , e4 >, h12 =< e1 + ce3, e2 >, h13 =< e3 + coe1, e4 >, h14 =< e1 + e4, e2 >, h15 =< e3 ± e2 , e4 >, h16 =< e1 + e3 , e2 ± e4 >
3 h17 =< e1,e3,e2 >,h18 =< e1,e4,e2 >, h19 =< el, e3 , e4 >, h20 =< e2 , e3 , e4 >, h21 =< e1 ± e3, e2, e4 >, h22 =< e1 + coe3, e2, e4 >
92
Now we are going to study all possible invariant reductions of the main equation (22).
Let us first note that the subgroups H1, H3, and H6 generated by
3 3 3 3 subalgebras h =< — >, h3 =< ert — > and h6 =<-+ ert — > correspon-
& 1 dV 3 dl 6 dV dl F
dingly, do not give us any interesting reductions so we omit the detailed study of these cases here. We start with the first interesting and nontrivial case. Case H2 (h2). The subalgebra h2 is spanned by the generator e3
¿И^,пФ<())|+1| >• <43)
h2 =< e3 >=< — ______v
ar ^ J ' dl r dt
To find all invariants of the subgroup H2 we solve the related characteristic system of equations
dl dt dV dh
-1 (e" \e-«dInФ^)) 1 0 0 arv J ' r
where the last two equations of the system present a formal notation that shows that the independent variable h and the dependent variable V are now invariants under the action of the subgroup H2 . We can obtain other independent invariants solving the system above. So we obtain a set of independent invariants
inv1 = z = l +—ert \e-rtdln ®(i)-—ln ®(f) - — (1 + ln a), inv2 = h, (45) ar J ar ar
inv3 = W( z, h) = V(l, h, t). (46)
The invariants (45) can be used as the new independent variables z, h and the invariant (46) as the new dependent variable W(t, z) to reduce the three-dimensional PDE (22) to a two-dimensional one
-rfh2Whh + (/u-S)hWh + (rz + Sh)Wz +1 Wz ln Wz (47)
2 a
- (a - r)2 Wz + 2(a - r)yphWzWA + V2p2a2h2Wj =Q
2^2Wzz '
In (21) we describe the boundary condition and in Lemma 1 we formulate the main properties of the value function. Now we have to reformulate the boundary condition on the function W(z, h) after the substitution (45). To make further remarks transparent we take first as an example the simples form of the liquidation time distribution and suppose that ®(i) = e-Kt, i.e. we have to do with exponential liquidation time distribution. Then the new variable z will take the form
ic 1 (к . Л z = l+—t+—I — 1 - In a
ar ar ^ r
It means that z is increasing if l and/or t are growing up. But it leads to contradiction between the properties of the function W(z, h) = V(l, h, t). On one side the boundary condition demands that the value function tends to zero for t ^x, other sides that the same function is strictly increasing by l ^-x. Because after the invariant substitution the new variable z is the sum of these two old variables l and t we are not able to solve this contradiction. A similar inconsistency problem arising if we use another form of
the function ®(t). Following this reduction cannot be used to solve the optimization problem.
Case H4(h4). Now we look for invariants of the subgroup H4. The corresponding subalgebra h4 is spanned by the generator e1 + ae3, i.e.
h=<— (l-coert \e-rtd ln ®(t))- + -—- V— >. (49)
4 aA J ' dl r dt dV
We need to regard two special cases a = 0 and a ^ 0 here. If a = 0 then
h4 =< e-, >=< — —-V— >. (50)
41 ar dl dV
The invariants of the group H4 are
inv1 = h, inv2 = t, inv3 = W (h, t) = V (l, h, t)ead.
From the last relation follows that in this case, the value function has the form V(l, h, t) = e-arlW(h, t), and the complete dependence on l is described
just by the factor e-arl. It means that we obtain a decreasing function V(l, h, t) in the variable l in contradiction to the properties of a value function (see Lemma 1). It means that this reduction does not provide any meaningful solutions to our problem.
Now we can move according to a standard procedure to find the invariants of H4 when a ^ 0 . We obtain three independent invariants using a corresponding characteristic system
1 _ — _ t
inv, = z = l +—ert (e-rtdln ®(t)--ln ®(t)--, inv2 = h, (51)
av J av am
inv3 = W(z, h) = V(l, h, t)ea . (52)
Analogously substituting expressions for the invariants z as the new independent variable and W(z, h) as the new dependent variables into (22) we get
-if h2Whh + (/u-S)hWh + (rz + Sh)Wz +1 wz ln Wz 2 a
(a- r )2 W2 + 2{a - r )fPhWzWzh +rfp1a2 h2 Wj
2^2 Wzz
93
1 \ — + (1+ln a) | Wz - rW = 0.
a \a ) a
We prove now a compatibility of the invariant substitutions (51) and the boundary condition (21). As before we look for the new invariant variables (51) — (52) in the case of exponential liquidation time with ®(t) = e-Kt then these formulas take the form
t Km T K ,
z = l H--1H---, inv2= h, (54)
arm ar
- T-t
V(t, l, h) = W(z, h)e m , m * 0. (55)
94 From (54) follows that if we chose an arbitrary parameter m = - / k then
the variable z up to a constant shift coincides with the old variable l. The relation (55) shows that the boundary condition (21) is met with every solution to (53). We see also that for other positive values of the parameter m the invariant variables (54) — (55) are compatible with the boundary condition (21).
Similar to the case of the exponential time distribution we can study other types of liquidation time distributions. For instance, we look at the
frequently used Weibull distribution with ®(t) = e-(t/X) where the invariant variables will take the form
z = l H—^TTT e-r( k, rt) tk - — t, inv2= h, (56)
ar AK ar!k am
r
V(t, l, h) = W(z, h)e m, m * 0, (57)
here r( k, rt) is the upper incomplete gamma function.
For the studied optimization problem, the most interesting case appears if the liquidation time distribution has a local maximum as we expect it in the real world. The Weibull distribution has a local maximum for the parameter k >1. Because of the asymptotic behavior of the expression ertr(k, rt) ^ rk-1tk-1 as t we obtain that for k >1 the variable 1
z ^ l h--— tk as t . It means that also for the Weibull distribution we
ar!k
have compatibility of the invariant substitutions (56) —(57) with the boundary condition (21).
We notice that the investment n( z, h) and consumption c( z, t, h) in the
case H4 look as
VP°hWzh + (a- r )Wz
ti{z, h)= ----, c(z, t,h) = -ln
с Wz
a
m
aWz
+ — t, m>0,
am
where W( z, h) is a solution of the equation (48).
Case H5(h5). According to the first line of Table the subalgebra h5 corresponding to the subgroup H5 algebra is spanned by
h5 =< et ± e4 >=< i— ± ertV— >. (58)
514 V ar )dl dV
Using a standard procedure to determine the invariants of the subgroup H5 we obtain three independent invariants as a solution of the characteristic system, they have a form
inv1 = h, inv2 = t, inv3 = v(h, t) = e 1±arert V(l, h, t). (59)
It means also that the complete dependence of the value function
V(l, h, t) on the variable l is described just by the factor e 1±areT . If 1
t >—ln(ar) then the value function will be decreasing function in l by
r
ar
choosing the plus sign in the denominator of the fraction---1 and it
1 ± arer
will be increasing function in l if we choose the minus sign in the denominator of the fraction.
Because the value function for the optimization problem should be increasing function in l so we need to study just this one case. Therefore we
l
choose as a new dependent variable the function v(h, t) = e1-are V(l, h, t). Substituting the new dependent variable v(h, t) into (22) we get a two-dimensional PDE
1
ff f jz:,* W \
vt + h vhh + (M-<5)hvh +—rr-;
2 are -1
aSh -1 + ln
arert -1
W V
r ®(i)
v + v ln v
Jo-rt v - -(areTt - 1}2fp2 h 2 vl = 0, v(h,t)t^ 0.
2a a 2a r v
After Lemma 1 the value function V(l, h, t) cannot have exponential growth in l as we obtain it now. It means that the invariant substitution (59) is inconsistent with the possed optimization problem.
Case H7(h7). The last one-dimensional subalgebra in the list of the optimal system of subalgebras in Table is spanned by e2 ± e3
h7 =< e2 ± e3 >=< ±(-ar ('" I'"" +7 dt')+dV >• <60)
According to a standard procedure, we obtain following invariants of the subgroup H7
1 __1 _
inv1 = z = l +—ert (e-rtdln ®(f)--ln 0(f), inv2 = h, (61)
rty J rty
95
O—l
inv3 = W (z, h) = V(t, l, h)+rt. (62)
Using these invariants (61), (62) as the new variables z, h, W( z, h) and substituting them into (22) we obtain a two-dimensional PDE on W (z, h)
-if h2Whh + (/u-S)hWh + (rz + Sh)Wz +1 Wz ln Wz ±r (63)
2 a
-(«-r)2W2 + 2(a-r)lphWzWzh + fp2a2h2Wj | 1(- + n =Q 2a2 Wzz a z
96 In this case, we see the inconsistency between the boundary condition
(21) which demands that V(t, l, h) ^ 0 as t and the invariant
substitutions (61), (62) which say that the expression V(t, l, h)+rt depends just on z, h and not from the variable t.
There are a total of four meaningful reductions of the three-dimensional PDE (22) for the case of the EXP utility function and the general liquidation
time distribution ®(t) by using one-dimensional subalgebras of the algebra LEiXF. Just one of these reductions which correspond to the case H4 with co ^ 0, i.e. the substitutions (51), (52) are consistent with the boundary condition (21) and the two-dimensional PDE (53) is a corresponding reduction. This equation can be studied further with numerical methods.
In Table are listed also two and three-dimensional subalgebras of LE4XF . Using these subalgebras maybe we can find the deeper reductions of the PDE (22) for instance to ordinary differential equations.
Case H8(h8). We take the first two-dimensional subalgebra listed in Table, i.e. the subalgebra h8 =< e1,e3 >. We rewrite the characteristic systems to the first generator e1 in terms of the invariants of e3 (45), (46)
1 d d
then e1 takes the form e1 =---W-. Solving a corresponding chara-
ar dz dW
cteristic system we obtain a new invariant
inve = v(h) = W( z, h)earz, (64)
"1
which we use now as a new dependent variable to reduce the equation (47) to an ODE
1 „2,2 » V2P2 h 2 И' , f (.H-8W - (a- r )Лр
h2v h2+
2 2 v
a2
hv
f („ „\2 A
v - rv ln(-flrv) = 0. (65)
(a- r )2
arSh +-
2a y
In terms of original variables l, h, t, and V(l, h, t) the substitution looks as follows
V (l, h, t ) = v( h )e -
(66)
= i +_Lert (e-rtd ln ®(t) -—ln ®(t) - — (1 + ln a).
ar J ar ar
Now we obtain a reduction of the three-dimensional PDE (22) to an ODE. But we cannot use this reduction, because it is inconsistent with the properties of the value function V (l, h, t) listed in the Lemma 1. The value function is an increasing function in variable l and V(l, h, t) > 0, it means also v(h) should be a positive function. From the first expression in (66) follows that V(l, h, t) is decreasing in z and following in the variable l and from the equation (65) follows that the expression ln(-arv) is well defined just for negative functions v(h).
Case H 12(h12). Similar to the previous case we study now the case of h12 =< (e1 +®e3), e2 > and after the substitution
V (t, l, h) = v(h) exp arl - ert \e-rtd ln ®(t)+ln ®(t)) we obtain an ODE on the function v(h)
(67)
1 2/2 " T P ,2 —rj h v -
2J h 2 ivl
v
(/u - S)a2 - (a- r )rp
hv
(
arSh +
(a- r)
2
v + r(1 + ln a)v - rv ln(-arv) = 0.
(68)
If we can find a positive solution to this equation then we get the solution to the original optimization problem. It is easy to see that the last term in the equation (68) will be complex-valued if the function v(h) > 0. It means that it is not possible to find a positive solution to this equation. This reduction is not compatible with the conditions possed on the optimization problem. Like in the previous case we see that also other properties of the value function listed in Lemma 1 cannot be satisfied if the value function takes the form (67).
All other two — and three — dimensional subalgebras listed in Table do not give any meaningful reductions of the original equation (22), so we will not regard them in detail.
We studied the complete set of all possible reductions of the original three-dimensional PDE (22) to simpler differential equations. We see that not all of the reductions are reasonable for the optimization problem. Just one of them represented by the two-dimensional PDE satisfies all conditions. It is the main result of this Section and we formulate this result as a theorem
97
Theorem 4. The main three-dimensional HJB equation (22) admits the unique symmetry reduction to the two-dimensional FDE (53) after the substitutions (51) — (52) which satisfies all conditions of the posed optimization problem. The corresponding investment — consumption strategies are given in (58).
5. Conclusion
98
In this paper, we study a portfolio optimization problem for a basket consisting of a risk-free liquid, risky liquid, and risky illiquid assets where the investor prefers to use an exponential utility function. The illiquid asset is sold in a random moment T with a known distribution of the liquidation time. It is a distribution with a survival function ®(t), satisfying very general conditions (8). Typically one suppose that the liquidation time distribution is an exponential one, i.e. ®(t) = e-Kt, t > 0, ^>0, or of the
Weibull type with 0(t) = e-(t/1)k, with t > 0,k >0,2>0. The Weibull distribution turns to the exponential distribution by k = 1 and one can understand it as a generalization of the exponential distribution. Based on the economical motivation we choose k >1 because of in this case the Weibull probability density function has a local maximum.
Before in papers [3; 5] we studied similar portfolio optimization problems where the investor used the HARA and LOG utility functions correspondingly instead of the exponential utility function as in this paper.
Both the HARA utility function as well as the LOG utility function were widely used before in optimization problems with a random income and for different settings of the portfolio optimization problems. Usually, it was going on the optimization problems with a portfolio that includes an illiquid asset that was sold in a deterministic moment, i. e. on a portfolio optimization problem with a finite time horizon. Other authors supposed that the illiquid asset is not sold at all, i. e. they studied a portfolio optimization problem with the infinite time horizon. In previous papers [3], [5] we demonstrated the connection between these two problems. We also showed that for y ^ 0 we obtain UHARAy^0 ^ ULOG, as well as formally a
three-dimensional HJB equation (18) corresponding to the HARA utility function transforms into the HJB equation with the LOG utility function. Then we proved independently from the form of the survival function ®(t) that the Lie algebraic structure of the PDE with Lie logarithmic utility can be seen as a limit of the algebraic structure of the PDE with the HARA utility function as y ^ 0 .
Now we provided a complete Lie group symmetry analysis for the optimization problem with an exponential utility function, i.e. for the three-dimensional PDE (22) which contains an arbitrary function ®(t). The results are formulated in Theorem 2. We obtained that this PDE admits the four-dimensional Lie algebras LE4XF . We prove also that the optimization problems with different forms of exponential utility functions are equivalent
up to the one-to-one analytical substitution. In other words, the optimization problems are identical from any point of view: an economical, analytical or Lie algebraic one.
We also investigated a connection between the optimization problem with the HARA utility function (3) and with the EXP utility function in Section 3.1. Even though the HARA utility function is connected to the EXP utility function by y as we mentioned in (4) we do not get the expected connection between the corresponding optimization problems. Instead of that, we obtain quite different structures of the invariant variables by the study of the symmetry reductions of the main equation (22). In the case of
the HARA utility function, typical invariant variables were the fraction —
h
and time t. It means that in the case of the HARA or LOG utility function the value function depends in the first place from the relation between the values of the liquid and illiquid assets. It is completely independent of the absolute value of his liquid part or from the absolute value of his illiquid
part of wealth, but it depends on — . For instance, the investor in the HARA
h
case, as we proved it before, should increase his consumption rapidly if the
relation — falls, independently how many millions of dollars the investor h
has as liquid part at the moment.
Here in the case of the exponential utility function, the situation is quite different. As follows from equation (46), the behavior of the investor depends now on two variables, on the value of the illiquid asset h and on the combined variable z which contains the liquid part of wealth and an economically modulated time. As a consequence, the absolute value of the illiquid part of wealth plays a large role. The variable z tells us that the influence of a large amount of a liquid asset plays the same role as the possibility to wait a long time. By the way, this difference in the behavior of the invariant variables and the radical change of the investment-consumption strategies is to explain by the fact that the risk tolerance in the case of the HARA utility function is a linear function of the consumption c and in the
1
case of the exponential utility the risk tolerance is just a constant R(c) = — .
a
A further difference between the optimization problems with the HARA and an exponential utility function is related to the structure of the admitted Lie algebras. In the cases of the HARA and LOG utility functions, the corresponding three-dimensional PDEs have admitted three-dimensional main Lie algebras. Just by the special choice of a liquidation time distribution, i.e. only for the exponential function ®(t) = e-lct we got an extension of these Lie algebras to the four-dimensional ones. Here in the case of the exponential utility function, we obtain from the beginning the four-dimensional Lie algebra as the symmetry algebras of the corresponding PDE. It is remarkable that in this case the four-dimensional Lie algebras do
99
not allow any extension independently from the form of ®(t). It can be seen by the solving of the system of equation (31) in the proof of Theorem 2.
In the previous paper [3] we proved that the algebra LL4OG can be
obtained as a limit case of LH4ARA by y ^ 0. Here we see that L™^2 (or correspondingly LH4ARA2 ) and LE4XF are quite different and they do not connect by y ^x as well as they do not have any connections between analytical structures of their generators independently on the form of the liquidation time distribution.
In our paper, we pay attention to the internal structure of the admitted algebra LE4XF to obtain convenient and useful reductions of the main equation (22). Further on we use the system of optimal subalgebras provided in [22] and get corresponding nonequivalent invariant reductions of the three-dimensional PDEs (22) to two-dimensional PDEs. They describe the complete set of solutions that can not be transformed into each other with the help of the transformations of the admitted symmetry group. We show that the three-dimensional PDE can be reduced to corresponding two-dimensional ones in Section 4. The low-dimensional PDEs are much more convenient for further analytical or numerical studies. We also provide the formulas for the optimal investment-consumption policies in invariant variables using solutions of the reduced equation. We demonstrate that between meaningful reductions there exists one (53) which is consistent with the boundary condition (21) and with the expected properties of the value function.
We remark also a different level of influence of the parameters on the HJB equation and the admitted Lie algebraic structure. The HJB equation contains seven parameters r,a,a, /n,S,f, p which define the behavior of the liquid and illiquid asset, and one parameter a which is fixed by the exponential utility function. There are also some parameters which define the liquidation time distribution, for instance, it is the parameter k if we
take the exponential distribution with ®(t) = e-Kt or two parameters 2 and
k if we take the Weibull distribution with ®(t) = e-(t/1)k. If we look at the structure of the Lie algebra provided in Theorem 2 we see that the generators of the Lie algebra depend on the parameters r, a, and parameters of the liquidation time distribution only. The algebra changes their structure if one or some of these parameters vanishing. Roughly said the most influence on the form of the solution of this optimization problem has interest rate r, the type of the investor's utility function, and a marked defined liquidation time distribution for the illiquid asset. These parameters define the invariant variables and the analytical structure of the solutions.
Summing up, we carry a complete Lie group analysis for the optimization problem with the exponential utility function and for a general liquidation time distribution. We determine the reduced equation and corresponding optimal policies as it formulates in the Theorem 4.
The author is thankful to prof. L. Vostrikova-Jacod for interesting discussions and for organizing a very successful conference «Advanced Methods in Mathematical Finance» (Angers, France, 2018), where the author got the idea to write this paper.
References
1. Bordag L.A. Geometrical properties of differential equations. Applications of Lie group analysis in Financial Mathematics. Singapore, 2015.
2. Bordag L. A., Yamshchikov I. P. Lie group analysis of nonlinear Black-Scholes models // Ehrhardt M., Günther M., ter Maten E.J.W. (eds.). Novel Methods in Computational Finance. Springer, 2017. P. 109—128.
3. Bordag L. A., Yamshchikov I. P. Optimization problem for a portfolio with an illiquid asset: Lie group analysis // Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications. 2017. Vol. 453. P. 668—699.
4. Bordag L.A., Yamshchikov I.P., Zhelezov D. Portfolio optimization in the case of -
an asset with a given liquidation time distribution // International Journal of En- 101 gineering and Mathematical Modelling. 2015. Vol. 2 (2). P. 31 — 50.
5. L Bordag L.A., Yamshchikov I. P., Zhelezov D. Optimal allocation-consumption problem for a portfolio with an illiquid asset // International Journal of Computer Mathematics. 2016. Vol. 93 (5). P. 749— 760. doi: 10.1080/00207160.2013.877584.
6. Bordag L. A.Optimization problem for a portfolio with an illiquid asset in the case of an exponential utility function // Theory of Probability and its Applications. 2020. Vol. 65 (1). P. 155—157. doi: 10.4213/tvp5367.
7. Bouchard B., Pham H. Wealth-path dependent utility maximization in incomplete markets // Finance and Stochastics. 2004. Vol. 8 (4). P. 579 — 603.
8. Duffie D., Fleming W., Soner H.M., Zariphopoulou T. Hedging in incomplete markets with HARA utility // Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 1997. Vol. 21. P. 753 — 782.
9. Diaz A., Esparcia C. Assessing risk aversion from the investor's point of view // Frontiers in Psychology. 2019. 02 July. doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2019.01490.
10. Karoui N. El, Blanchet-Scalliet C., Jeanblanc M., Martinelli L. Optimal investment decisions when time-horizon is uncertain // Journal of Mathematical Economics. 2008. Vol. 44 (11). P. 1100—1113.
11. Ibragimov N. H. Lie group analysis of differential equations. CRS Press, 1994.
12. Jacod J., Shiryaev A. N. Limit theorems for stochastic processes. (Grundlehren der mathematischen Wissenschaften ; Vol. 288). Springer, 2002.
13. Meleshko S. V. Methods for Constructing Exact Solutions of Partial Differential Equations: Mathematical and Analytical Techniques with Applications to Engineering. Springer, 2005.
14. Meleshko S. V., Moyo S. On the complete group classification of the reaction-diffusion equation with a delay // Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications. 2008. Vol. 338 (1). P. 448 — 466.
15. Merton R. Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuous-time case // The Review of Economics and Statistics. 1969. Vol. 51 (3). P. 247—257.
16. Merton R. Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous time model // Journal of Economic Theory. 1971. Vol. 3. P. 373 — 413.
17. Monin P. Hedging market risk in optimal liquidation // SSRN Electronic Journal. 2014. Vol. 01.
18. Monin P., Zariphopoulou T. On the optimal wealth process in a log-normal market: Applications to risk management // International Journal of Financial Engineering. 2014. Vol. 01 (02). 1450013.
19. Olver P. J. Applications of Lie groups to differential equations. Springer Science & Business Media, 2000.
20. Ovsiannikov L. V. Group Analysis of Differential Equations. Academic Press, 1982.
21. Ovsyannikov L. V. The «podmodeli» program. Gas dynamics // Journal of Applied Mathematics and Mechanics. 1994. Vol. 58 (4). P. 601-627.
22. Patera J., Winternitz P. Subalgebras of real three- and four-dimensional Lie algebras // Journal of Mathematical Physics. 1977. Vol. 18 (7). P. 1449-1455.
23. Schied A., Schoneborn T. Risk aversion and the dynamics of optimal liquidation strategies in illiquid markets // Finance and Stochastics. 2009. Vol. 13 (2). P. 181-204.
24. Tartakovsky D.M., Dentz M. Diffusion in Porous Media: Phenomena and Mechanisms // Transp. Porous Med. 2019. Vol. 130 (1). P. 105-127. doi: 10.1007/s 11242-019-01262-6.
25. Vazquez J. L. The Porous Medium Equation: Mathematical Theory. Clarendon _ Press ; Oxford University Press, 2006.
102 26. Vazquez J.L. Smoothing and Decay Estimates for Nonlinear Diffusion Equa-
tions // Equations of Porous Medium Type. (Oxford lecture series in mathematics and its applications ; Vol. 33). Oxford University Press, 2006.
The author
Prof. Ljudmila A. Bordag, University of Applied Sciences Zittau/Görlitz, Germany. E-mail: [email protected]
Об авторе
Людмила Алексеевна Бордаг — проф., Университет прикладных наук Цит-тау/Гёрлиц, Германия.
E-mail: [email protected]