Научная статья на тему 'Optimal multiattribute screening'

Optimal multiattribute screening Текст научной статьи по специальности «Математика»

CC BY
57
6
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
Журнал
Ural Mathematical Journal
Scopus
ВАК
Область наук
Ключевые слова
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION / INCENTIVE CONTRACTING / MAXIMUM PRINCIPLE / NONLINEAR PRICING

Аннотация научной статьи по математике, автор научной работы — Weber Thomas A.

We provide a technique for constructing optimal multiattribute screening contracts in a general setting with one-dimensional types based on necessary optimality conditions. Our approach allows for type-dependent participation constraints and arbitrary risk proles. As an example we discuss optimal insurance contracts.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.

Текст научной работы на тему «Optimal multiattribute screening»

URAL MATHEMATICAL JOURNAL, Vol. 2, No. 2, 2016

OPTIMAL MULTIATTRIBUTE SCREENING1

Thomas A. Weber

Chair of Operations, Economics and Strategy Swiss Federal Institute of Technology, Lausanne, Switzerland [email protected]

Abstract: We provide a technique for constructing optimal multiattribute screening contracts in a general setting with one-dimensional types based on necessary optimality conditions. Our approach allows for type-dependent participation constraints and arbitrary risk profiles. As an example we discuss optimal insurance contracts.

Key words: Asymmetric Information, Incentive Contracting, Maximum Principle, Nonlinear Pricing.

1. Introduction

Starting with the seminal contribution by Mirrlees [1], optimal screening contracts have found many applications in economics, including taxation, nonlinear pricing, and the regulation of monopolies [1-4]. The underlying game of asymmetric information contains two periods. In the first period, the principal announces a menu of attribute bundles to an agent who possesses private information about his utility function, and who can select an attribute bundle by sending a message to the principal. In the second period, allocations are made according to a publicly known enforceable mapping from the message space to both attribute bundles and monetary transfers from agent to principal. Subject to the agent's participation constraint (individual rationality) and the agent's self-interested choice behavior (incentive compatibility), an optimal screening menu maximizes the principal's expected payoff. In this paper, which is related to [5,6], we provide an explicit method to construct optimal screening contracts with continuously distributed, one-dimensional "types" representing the agents' private information and multiple instruments (or attributes), based on necessary optimality conditions. The problem of finding optimal screening contracts can be formulated as an optimal control problem, for which we derive necessary optimality conditions using the maximum principle by Pontryagin et al. [7] and the technique of successive approximation [8]. In this vein, the method approximates an optimal schedule by directly computable solutions to a sequence of relaxed screening problems. We allow for type-dependent participation constraints and payoff functions that are nonlinear in each contract instrument. This is useful when considering the effects of variable outside options and/or risk-aversion on the optimal contracts. The set of participating types is also subject to optimization.

The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we introduce a general model for multiattribute screening and formulate the principal's optimization problem in an optimal-control setting. In Section 3, we provide a full set of necessary optimality conditions that can be used to construct a solution to the screening problem, including an iterative approximation method. In Section 4, we discuss the design of a menu of optimal insurance contracts for an agent with unknown risk aversion as a practical example. Section 5 concludes.

1This paper was presented as a plenary lecture in October 2016 in Ekaterinburg, at the International Conference on "Systems Analysis: Modeling and Control" in memory of Academician Arkady Kryazhimskiy.

2. Model

2.1. Screening Problem

We consider a standard screening setup with a principal ("she") and an agent ("he"). The agent's possible type 9, known only to him, lies in the type space 0 = [0,1].2 The type 9 summarizes all the private information the agent has. From the principal's viewpoint it is distributed with the continuous probability density f = F on the support 0.3 The principal designs a schedule of instruments (or attributes) x = (x0, x1,..., xn) : 0 ^ R++1 so as to maximize her expected payoff,

V(x; 0o)= T V(x(6),6)f (9) d9, (2.1)

Je o

where n > 1 is a given integer which denotes the number of attributes characterizing the bundle, and 0o = [9o, 1] C 0 is the set of participating types, with the marginal type 90 € 0 subject to optimization.4 In order to ensure implementability of a favored attribute schedule, the principal's optimization problem is subject to the agent's self-interested behavior, which manifests itself in the form of two constraints. First, given that an agent of type 9 has net utility U(£, 9) for a bundle £ € R++1, the optimal type announcement § satisfies the incentive-compatibility constraint

U(x(§),9) > U(x(9), 9), V§,0 € 00. (2.2)

Second, since the agent is free to walk away from the principal's proposed menu of contracts (attribute schedule), the participation set 0o is defined by the agent's participation constraint

§,9 € 0o ^ U(x(§),9) > U(0,9). (2.3)

That is, an agent of type 9 participates if by pretending to be any other participating agent type § (including himself) he achieves a utility that is at least equal to the utility derived from a zero bundle (corresponding to nonparticipation). The principal's screening problem is to find an (absolutely continuous) attribute schedule x(-) which maximizes the objective in (2.1) subject to the implementability constraints (2.2) and (2.3).

2.2. Key Assumptions

The attribute x0 corresponds to a numéraire good such as a monetary transfer from the agent to the principal.5 The principal's payoff function V : Rra+1 x 0 ^ R is continuously differentiable in the attribute vector x and continuous in the type Q. In addition, we make the following two assumptions on V.

P1. Vx0 > 0 >VXi for all i € {1,...,n} (P-Monotonicity).6 P2. V(0, Q) > 0 for all Q € 0 (Possibility of Inaction).

2Using a simple affine transformation this does in fact allow for any compact interval on the real line.

3Throughout we use the dot-notation for total derivatives with respect to Q, e.g., F = dF.

4The problem of maximizing the principal's expected utility can be viewed as a "dynamic optimization problem" if V(x; Q0) represents an average payoff generated by a trajectory x(Q) on the time interval [Q0, 1], where the starting time Q0 is subject to optimization. The methods presented in this paper extend to intervals of the form [Q0,Q\] where both boundaries are subject to optimization (cf. footnote 23).

5We sometimes use x to denote bundles (i.e., points) in the attribute space R++1 = {x € Rn+1 : x > 0} rather than full schedules (i.e., functions); the same 'notational flexibility' is used for components xi of x.

6Throughout the text, we denote partial derivatives using subscripts, e.g., Vx0 = dV/dx0.

Agent type 9's net utility from the bundle x is U(x, 9), where U : Rn+2 ^ R is a twice continuously differentiable function. His outside option (which is realized after not agreeing to any of the principals' proposed contracts) yields the reservation utility r(9) = U(0, 9), where r : R ^ R is a continuously differentiable function. We make the following three assumptions on U.

A1. For all (x,9) € R++1 x 8: (i) Ue(0,xi,... ,x,n,8) > r(9), and (ii) UXi(x,9) > 0 > UXQ(x,9) for all i € {1,... ,n} (A-Monotonicity).

A2. For all (xi,...,x,n,9) € R+ x 8: (i) U (0,xi,... ,x,n,9) > r(9) (Attribute Desirability), and (ii) r(9) > limXQ^^ U(xo, x1,..., xn, 9) (Transfer Sensitivity).

A3. For all (x, 9) € R++1 x 8: \UX., e (x, 9)| > 0 for some i' € {1,... ,n} (Incentive Regularity).7

Finally, to exclude unbounded screening contracts, the gains from trade between the principal and the agent need to be bounded. To formalize this notion, we first introduce the principal's equivalent variation E(x1,..., xn, 9), which corresponds to the minimum payment in terms of the numeraire good xo she would be willing to accept to provide the attribute bundle (x1,..., xn) to the agent, i.e.,

E (x1,...,xn,9) = inf {xo € R+ : V (xo,xu ... ,xn,9) > 0}, (2.4)

where we adopt the convention that inf 0 = to. On the other hand, agent type 9's compensating variation C(x1,... ,xn,9) is his maximum willingness to pay (in terms of x0) for the attribute bundle (x1,... ,xn) provided by the principal, i.e.,

C (x1, ...,xn,9) = sup {xo € R+ : U (xo, x1, ...,xn,9) > r(9)} , (2.5)

where we adopt the convention that sup 0 = —to. The following assumption guarantees that gains from trade between principal and agent exist and the contracts between the two involve only bounded attribute bundles. Let

X = {(xo,x1,...,xn) € R++1 : C (x1,...,xn,9) > xo > E (xh ... ,x,n,9) and 9 € 8}

be the (feasible) contract space.8

T1. X is bounded (Bounded Contract Space).

We now comment on the six assumptions P1, P2, A1-A3, and T1. Assumption P2 bounds the principal's value of the screening problem from below by zero, since the zero schedule x = 0 is always feasible. Assumption P1 means that the principal's preferences are nonsatiated in the numeraire good. The monotonicity of the principal's payoff with respect to the non-numeraire attributes (x1,... ,xn) is unimportant and can be relaxed in situations which involve cooperation between the principal and the agent. Correspondingly, we assume in A1(ii) that the agent dislikes paying the numeraire to the principal, but finds all other attributes desirable. The first inequality in P1 and A1(ii) can be always satisfied by relabelling and simple sign-transformations, as long as there is one attribute that both the principal and the agent like, so it is possible for the agent to compensate the principal for her actions regarding the other attributes. Assumption A1(i) guarantees that the set of participating types is convex (of the form 8o = [9o, 1] for some 9o €

7Without any loss of generality, we assume in what follows that i' = 1; furthermore, R++1 = int(R++1).

8 The equivalent and compensating variations are classical welfare measures [9]. A normative relationship between them, in particular a lack of exchange due to the endowment effect (when E > C) for identical individuals, is discussed by [10]. Here, assumptions A1 and P1 imply that the contracting parties' preferences differ, and assumptions A2 and P2 that gains from trade exist.

[0,1]) and includes the highest type 9 = 1,9 as long as it is nonempty. The latter is guaranteed by P2, since the principal can always provide the zero-attribute bundle at no disbenefit. The first inequality in A2 means that any agent always accepts the bundle (0,x1,... ,xn) € R++1 when he obtains the non-numeraire attributes for free. The second inequality means that for any attribute vector (x-\^,... ,xn) € R+ there is a price (in terms of x0) that is too high. The incentive-regularity condition A3 requires that the agent perceives increasing (or decreasing) differences with respect to one non-numeraire attribute and his type. This condition is needed only in a neighborhood of points where the agents' incentive compatibility becomes a binding constraint. Finally, the assumption T1 stipulating that the gains from trade be bounded is naturally satisfied in any practical situation, e.g., when both U and V are bounded and there exists an e such that UXo < -e< 0 < e < VXo. Intuitively it is enough when the principal's marginal costs -VXi of providing a bundle (to a given agent type) increase fast enough in the attributes, and at the same time the agent's marginal utilities UXi for these attributes decrease. Assumption T1 guarantees that the solution to the principal's screening problem behaves as if it were constrained to attribute schedules with values in the set X without the need for an explicit consideration of this constraint. Note that assumptions P2 and A2 imply that the contract space is nonempty, as it must contain the zero bundle, i.e., 0 € X.

3. Optimal Screening Contracts

We treat the screening problem in an optimal-control framework. Accordingly, the admissible schedules x : 0 ^ R++1 are in the Sobolev space of absolutely continuous functions with

essentially bounded derivatives, and the corresponding class of admissible controls u : 0 ^ Rn is the Lebesgue space L^ of all essentially bounded functions. An admissible marginal type is any 90 € 0. Correspondingly, let D = L^(0, R++1) x W1;^(0, Rn) x 0 be the domain of admissibility for solutions (x*,u*, 9q) to the screening problem.10

Theorem 1. Under assumptions P1 and A1-A2, the principal's screening problem can be written in the form:

sup V(x; 90), (P)

(x,u,e0)&v

subject to

x = $(x, 9)u, U(x(90), 90) = r(90), (3.1)

and

min{(ê - ê)(Ue(x(ê), ê) - Ue(x(ê), ê)) } > 0, (3.2)

for all ê e ©o = [ê0,1], where11

<fi(x, ê)

In

$(x, ê) =

and In denotes an (n x n)-identity matrix.

e R(n+i)- ^(x, ê) = - (Uxi(x, 0)>-y>UXn (X,0)) > 0,

Uxo (X,ê)

(3.3)

Proof. Given an admissible schedule x : 0 ^ Rra+1, we conclude from A1 that U(x(Q),Q1) — r(Q1 ) > U(x(Q),Q0) — r(Q0) for any Q, Q1,Q0 € 0 with Q1 > Q0. Thus, type Q0's participation

9 Convexity of ©o can be achieved also when U — r is only quasiconcave in ê [11], in which case the upper marginal type becomes subject to optimization also.

10At an optimal solution (x*,u*, 0q), the schedule x* and control u* need only be defined on the optimal participation set ©* = [ê*, 1] Ç ©.

11A vector y = (yi,..., yn) e Rn satisfies y > 0 if and only if y > 0 for all i e {1,..., n}.

implies participation for all types 9 € ©0 = [90,1]. Since by P1 and A1 it is Vx0 > 0 > Ux0, the lowest participating type 90 cannot get any surplus, so necessarily U(x(90), 90) = r(90). The lowest type 90 is itself subject to optimization. Equation (3.1) states that d(x\,... ,xn)/d9 = u, where u is subject to optimization. When searching for schedules x : © ^ Rn+1 that maximize expected profits F(x; 90), by the revelation principle [12,13] the principal can restrict attention to schedules under which all types report truthfully,12 so

U(x(9), 9) > U(x(9), 9) (3.4)

for all 9,9 € ©. The incentive-compatibility condition (3.4) is equivalent to (3.1)-(3.3). To prove this, we first show that (3.4) implies (3.1)-(3.3). Indeed, by subtracting U(x(9), 9) from (3.4) and switching the labels for 9 and 9 we obtain that

U(x(9), 9) - U(x(9), 9) > U(x(9), 9) - U(x(9), 9)

and

U(x(9), 9) - U(x(9), 9) > U(x(9), 9) - U(x(9), 9). Combining the last two inequalities yields

U(x(9), 9) - U(x(9), 9) > U(x(9), 9) - U(x(9), 9) > U(x(9), 9) - U(x(9), 9) (3.5) for all 9,9 € ©. Selecting any 9,9 € int © and taking the limit for 9 ^ 9+ and 9 ^ 9- we get

= U (x(9), 9)

almost everywhere (a.e.) on ©, which is equivalent to

Ux(x(9), 9) x(9) = 0. (3.6)

The last equation defines the system dynamics x(9) = $(x(9),9)u(9) on ©0, as specified in (3.1) and (3.3). Note that x0( 9) = ^>(x( 9), 9) by solving (3.6) for x0. The fact that

p(x, 9) = (<pi(x, 9),...,<pn(x, 9)) > 0

(componentwise) follows directly from A1. Since by admissibility of the menu x and smoothness of U, the function U(x( ), ) is absolutely continuous in , by the fundamental theorem of calculus [14, p. 134] it is

U(x(9), 9) - U(x(9), 9)=/ Ue(x(ti),ti) dti. (3.7)

Je

The fundamental theorem of calculus also implies that

U(x(9), 9) - U(x(9), 9)=/ Ue(x(9),$) cM, (3.8)

Je

so by subtracting (3.7) from (3.8) one can rewrite the first inequality in (3.5) in the form

id

Ue(x(d),ti) - Ue(x(ß),ti)

dtf> 0

12The revelation principle describes the (almost trivial) fact that when the principal is able to commit to a mechanism (i.e., an allocation function x : © ^ X) by solving the agent's problem (2.2) of announcing a type $ = $*(9) € ©o that maximizes his expected utility, she can simply choose x, with x(9) ^ x($*(9)), instead of x to obtain a mechanism that reveals the agent's type truthfully.

for all 0,0 € 0. This last inequality holds for all 0,0 € 0 if and only if

f Ue(x(0), 0) > Ue(x(0), 0), if 0 > 0,

\ Ue(x(0), 0) < Ue(x(0), 0), if 0 < 0,

i.e., if and only if the single-crossing condition (3.2) is satisfied for all 0 € 0o. Hence, condition (3.4) is necessary for conditions (3.1)-(3.3) in Theorem 1. In order to show that conditions (3.1)-(3.3) are also sufficient for the incentive compatibility constraint (3.4), consider any 0,0 € 0 and rewrite (3.4) using the integral representation (3.7) and the fundamental theorem of calculus as

ç e çQ

U(x(0), 0) - U(x(0), 0)= Ue(x(ti),ti) dti > Ue(x(0),tf) diï = U(x(0), 0) - U(x(0), 0),

Je Je

or in the more compact form

Ue(x(0),V) - Ue(x(ß),ti)

dtf> 0.

This last inequality holds for all 0,0 € 0 if and only if Ue(x, 0) exhibits the single-crossing property (3.2) for all 0 € 0, which yields the desired sufficiency of (3.1)-(3.3) for (3.4). As alluded to earlier, the initial condition in (3.1) is due to the agent's participation constraint, U(x(0), 0) > r(0) for all 0 € 0o. By A2, the set of participating types 0o is nonempty (given that X = 0). □

e

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

The intuition for the system dynamics in (3.1) is that, except for the component x0 (which contains the agent's payment in the numeraire good), the rate of change of the principal's schedule x as a function of the type 0 is governed by the control variable u. The dynamics of the system are constrained by the fact that a participating agent 0 € [00, 1] needs to find it optimal to report his type truthfully, such that U(x(0), 0) > U(x(0), 0). In other words, by consuming a bundle x(0) possibly different from the bundle x( 0) designed for him, agent 0 cannot be better off. This incentive compatibility (or "implementability") is responsible for the dynamics of x0 and the constraint (3.2). The latter constraint renders problem (P) a nonstandard optimal control problem,13 for it involves the schedule x generically at different points of the type space. Hence, the corresponding necessary optimality conditions, summarized by the following result, differ from standard versions of the maximum principle. The existence of a solution to (P) is implied by [11, Thm. 2]. We now provide a set of necessary optimality conditions.

Theorem 2. Given that assumption T1 is satisfied, let (x*,u*, 00) be an optimal solution to the screening problem (P) and let 0q = [000, 1] be the corresponding set of participating types. Then there exists a function ^ = (^0,..., ^n) : 00 ^ Rn+1 of bounded variation, a constant A0 > 0, and a nonnegative Borel measure v, such that the following optimality conditions are satisfied.

C1. Adjoint Equation: ^(0) € Rn+1 satisfies

0) = ^ (\0Vx(x*,<d)f (f) + ^x(x*,#)u*) d<& - [\p(x*, #) - <&)Uxe(x0,<d) dv, Je Je

for all 0 € 000, where the measurable selection p satisfies14

p(x, 0) € arg imiii {(0 - 0) (Ue(x*(0), 0) - Ue(x, 0)) } ,

13In the remainder of the text, references to problem (P) (or to its relaxation (P') introduced below) include the complete problem setting with assumptions and relevant constraints.

14 A set-valued minimizer of a continuous function over a compact set is nonempty, compact-valued, and upper semi-continuous in 0. It therefore has a measurable selection [15, p. 44].

for any (x, 9) € Rn+1 x ©0-

C2. Maximality:

ul(9) = 0 ^ ^(9Mx*(9), 9) + ^(9) = 0, a.e. on ©0, for all i € {1,... ,n}.

C3. Transversality:

(i) 9* = 0 ^ 3 Ai € R : (0) + XiUx(x*(0), 0) = 0;

(ii) 9* > 0 ^ 4>(9*)(U$(x*( 9*), 9*) - r(9*)) + A0V(x *(9*), 9**)Ux(x*(90), 9*) = 0.

C4- Complementary Slackness:

supp(v) C <^9 € © : miii {( 9 - 9) (ue(x*(9), 9) - Ue(x*(9), 9))} = ^ .

C5. Nontriviality: A0 +supeee* 9)|| > 0.

Proof. See appendix. □

The adjoint variable 9) corresponds to the shadow value of the optimal attribute schedule at type 9, given that the evolution of the optimal schedule satisfies the ordinary differential equation (ODE) in (3.1) as well as the incentive-compatibility constraint (3.2). The adjoint equation C1 describes the evolution of ^ on the set of participating types. In particular, the shadow value of the attribute schedule vanishes for the highest type, 9 = 1. The maximality condition C2 requires that the optimal control u can be essentially bounded only if, while maximizing the principal's expected payoff, the gradient of $u with respect to u (corresponding to the right-hand side of (3.1)) vanishes. The transversality condition C3 is implied by the optimality of the marginal agent of type 0 , who is indifferent between participating or not. If 9* is not a boundary solution (i.e., when 9* > 0), condition C3 (ii) means that the total change in value, as measured by the agent's marginal surplus through the change in his type movement (evaluated at the shadow value 9*)) plus his marginal utility for the attribute bundle (evaluated at the principal's net payoff V(x*(9*), 90*)) must vanish for the indifferent type 9*. If it is optimal to serve all agents (i.e., when 9* =0), one obtains a distortion of the shadow values described by the transversality condition C3 (i). The complementary slackness condition C4 shows that the support of the measure v must be inside the set of types for which the incentive-compatibility constraint (3.2) is binding. Thus, if (3.2) is never binding, then v vanishes. Condition C5 ensures that the necessary optimality conditions are nontrivial in the sense that A0 and v cannot vanish together. This can imply an important simplification: if v = 0, then necessarily A0 > 0, so that, without any loss in generality, we can set A0 = 1, since all other optimality conditions are positively homogeneous in A0.

It is generally difficult to construct a measure v without the precise knowledge of x*, since p is defined using x* and 9*. When taking the limit 9 9 in the maximand of the left-hand side in (3.2), the following constraint is implied:

Y • u > 0, (3.2')

where y = (1,Y2,..., Yn) and Yj = Uxj$/Uxi$ corresponds to the agent's marginal rate of substitution (with respect to Ue) between x1 and xj for j € {2,..., n}. We refer to (P) with constraint (3.2) replaced by (3.2') therefore as the relaxed screening problem (P'). Contrary to the screening problem (P), the relaxed screening problem (P') can be solved explicitly.

Theorem 3. Under assumptions P1, P2, and A1-A3, if (x*,u*, e*) is an optimal solution to the relaxed screening problem (P'), then there exists an absolutely continuous function 0 : © ^ Rn+1 such that the transversality condition C3 is satisfied, and15

-0 = Vx(x*, d)f (e) + (0*px(x*, e) + HYx(x*, e)) u*, ^(1) = 0, (3.9)

and

[0oPx + IYx, $]u * = 0ope + lYe - fVx$, (3.10)

where i = 0op1(x *, e) + 01, and ¡7 • u* = 0.

Proof. Apply the optimality conditions in Theorem 2 to the optimal control problem (P'). For this, consider the Hamiltonian H = X0Vf + 0 • $u, and first examine the case where the constraint (3.2') is not binding, i.e., where 7 • u* > 0. If the optimal control u* is "proper," i.e., independent of u, then the maximality condition with respect to the relaxed screening problem (P') implies that Hu = 0$ = 0 on an optimal state-control trajectory. Differentiating both sides with respect to e, taking into account the adjoint equation, yields

-0i = - (Vx0 f + 0oPxq • u *) Pi + 0*Pi,x$u * + 0oPi,e = Vxi f + 0oPxi • u * (3.11)

for any i £ {1,... ,n}. These n equations can be rewritten more compactly in the form

[0oPx, $] u* = 0*pe - fVx®. (3.12)

In the case where 7 • u* = 0, maximization of the Hamiltonian subject to (3.2') yields the optimality condition 0$ = vy, where i > 0 is the corresponding Lagrange multiplier. The first component of this condition yields that i = 0op1(x *, e) + 01 as claimed. □

The Lagrange multiplier i is associated with the relaxed incentive-compatibility constraint (3.2'). By eliminating u* from the above relations and from (3.1), a solution to the relaxed screening problem can therefore be obtained by solving a system of n + 3 ODEs.

Corollary 1. Let assumptions P1, P2, and A1-A3 be satisfied, and let (x*,u*, e*) be an optimal solution to the relaxed screening problem (P'). (i) If the matrix R = [px, $] is nonsingular at the optimal solution, then there exist absolutely continuous functions 0o,01 : ©0 ^ R such that

{ x* = $r-1 - rn-), (3.13)

{ -i)o = Vxq f + Pxq R 1 (0oPe - fVx$),

providedthat y^R-1 (pe - ^VXr) > 0. (ii) Otherwise, setting 7 = (y2,... ,Yn) and u = (u2,... ,un)), there exist absolutely continuous functions 0o,01 : ©0 ^ R such that

x* = $ UoPx + 01 Yx, $1 (0o0e + 01Ye - fVx$) ,

■ r -1-1 (( -) (3.14)

-0i = Vxi f + (0oPxi + 01Yxi) 00 Px + 017x, $J [0o0e + 01Ye - fVx $J ,

for i £ {0,1}. (iii) The boundary conditions for both (3.13) and (3.14) are U(x*(e*), e*) = r(e*) and 0(1) = 0.

15Given two matrices A £ Rmxi and B £ Rixm, where m,l are positive integers, the Lie bracket of A and B is given by [A, B] = AB - (AB)T = AB - BTAT £ Rmxm, where (-)T denotes the transpose of (•).

To obtain the n + 2 initial values x(90) and 90 for the system (3.13), one can use the n + 1 transversality conditions C3 in conjunction with the initial condition in (3.1).

Remark 1. In the case where all payoff functions are quasilinear in the numeraire, it is <^X0 = 0 and VX0 = 1, which implies that ^0(9) = 1 — F(9) by virtue of (3.13), provided that

№— T—ff^) >0■ <3-»

The last inequality can be checked ex ante. It generalizes the standard Spence—Mirrlees sorting condition [16, Eq. (7), p. 155]. Note that the last inequality (3.15) features all primitives of the problem, and it is satisfied if the relaxed incentive-compatibility constraint (3.2') is not binding.

Remark 2. In the case where R = 0, as in the optimal insurance example discussed in Section 4, relation (3.10) immediately implies that

fotpe + we = fVx$. (3.16)

Solving this n-dimensional optimality condition, one can determine real-valued functions qi, such that

Xi = Qi(xo,d,^o), i €{1,...,n}, (3.17)

which then allows for the solution of the Hamiltonian system consisting of the state equation in (3.1) and the adjoint equation (3.9).

If the solution to the relaxed screening problem (P') is feasible in the screening problem (P), then it is also a solution to the principal's screening problem. Failing that, we can approximate an optimal solution to (P) by solutions to appropriate relaxed problems. For this we introduce a sequence of relaxed screening problems {(Pki)}ki>r For any k,l > 1, problem (P'kl) is identical to problem (P') with V replaced by

x _ xk-1'1-1

Vkl(x, O) = V(x, O) - k (g-(x, O; xk-1'-1)) - l and

g-(x,d; xk-1'l-1)= min (o, (O - O) (Ue(xk-1'l-1(d),0) - Ue(x,0))} ee[eg,i] L v n

for any (x,d) € Rra+1 x ©. We denote a solution to problem (Pjtl) by (xkl,ukl,9kl). To initialize the sequence of relaxed screening problem, we set V00 = V, thus adding a problem (P00) which is identical to problem (P'); its solution (x00, u00,0°°) is therefore described by our earlier results.

Theorem 4. (i) For any given k > 1, the sequence {(xkl,ukl,9kl)}^I of solutions to (Pkl) merges to (xk ,uk ,9k) € solution (x*,u*,9q) of (P).

U>I

converges to (xk,uk,9k) € WI>œ x x 0. (ii) The sequence {(xk,uk,9k)}k>I converges to a

Proof. (i) Fix any k > 1. The sequence {xkl }l>1 is by construction a Cauchy sequence in the Banach space L2(0), and therefore converges strongly. This implies weak convergence of the sequence {ukl}l> 1. Lastly, by the Bolzano—Weierstrass theorem the sequence {00kl}l>1 C © contains a convergent subsequence with limit in ©. Consider the limits d0j < 00k of any two such convergent subsequences. Then U(xk(dik),dik) = r(90k) and U(xk(Oik),9o) = r(0jk). On the other hand, as already noted in the proof of Theorem 1, by A1 for any O € [00o, 1] it is U(x(0),^0k) -r(^0k) <

U (x(0),0k )—r(0k ), so necessarily U (x(0),0)—r(0) = 0 for all 0 € [0k, 0k ]. Without loss of generality, we can therefore take 0k = liminf¡^^ 0kl. The limit (xk,uk ,0k) solves the relaxed screening problem (P') with V replaced by Vk(x, 0) = V(x, 0) — k (g-(x, 0; xk))2. (ii) The convergence of the sequence {0k}k>1 C 0 to 0* € 0 obtains as in part (i). Furthermore, any limit (x*,u*,O0) of the sequence {(xk ,uk ,0k)} k> 1 satisfies g-(x*(0),0; x*) = 0 a.e. on 0*, and is thus a feasible solution to the screening problem (P), provided that (x*,u*) € x L^. The latter follows from the

existence of a solution to (P). □

4. Application: Optimal Insurance

Consider the problem of designing a nonlinear insurance contract with multiple contingencies, which dates back at least to Stiglitz [17]. An agent has constant absolute risk aversion 0 € 0 = [0,1].16 The type parameter 0 belongs to the agent's private information, and—from the principal's point of view—it is distributed with the differentiable probability density f > 0 on the type space 0.17 The agent's utility for any real-valued monetary payoff £ is

v(£,0) = — exp (—0£),

and his current wealth is zero. The agent faces n possible, mutually exclusive loss events L1,..., Ln, which are ordered by magnitude such that 0 < L1 < • • • < Ln < to. The probability of loss event Li is pi > 0, so po = 1 — (p1 + • • • + pn) € (0,1) is the probability that no loss event occurs.18 An insurance contract subsidizes the agent by an amount xi when loss event Li occurs, and asks the agent for a net payment of x0 in the absence of a loss. Given an insurance contract x = (x0,..., xn), the agent's expected utility is

n

U(x, 0) = pov(—xo,0) + Piv(xi — Li, 0).

i=1

The agent's reservation utility without contract is therefore

n

r(0) = U(0,0) = —po + Y,Piv(—Li, 0).

i=1

On the other hand, the principal's expected payoff is

n

V(x, 0) = poxo — YPixi,

i=1

independent of 0. It is straightforward to verify that both the agent and the principal have utility functions which satisfy assumptions A1-A3 and P1-P2, respectively. The principal's equivalent variation in (2.4) is

E(x1,...,xn,0) = V( x

tî\ poj

while the agent's compensating variation in (2.5) takes the form

C (£l,...,x„,0) = (1)ln

16By a change of units (i.e., renormalization) this is without loss of generality; cf. also footnote 2.

17To satisfy assumption T1, the agent's risk aversion needs to be strictly positive. By considering 0/0 instead of 0, the analysis generalizes to positive risk aversions in [0, 0], for any 0 > 0.

18 The vector (po,... ,pn) lies in the interior of the n-simplex A„ = {(po,.. .,pn) € R++1 : po + • • •+p>n = 1}-

Thus, assumption T1 is satisfied as long as f (e) = 0 on [0, e] for some minimum risk-aversion e £ (0,1). When the agent is risk-neutral, then the principal would be willing to offer an actuarially fair contract to the agent. By continuous completion for e — 0+ (or, alternately, by imposing a very small capital cost on the principal), we can include risk-neutral agents who are then offered a zero contract. Using the optimality conditions in Theorem 2 and Corollary 1, we find that the Lie product R = [px, $] vanishes identically, so by Remark 3:

/ w f (PoPi - Pi) - IYie i1 - e-e(x0-yi))pof + (po/pi)iYie { , , .

(x* - Vi) 0o =-zp.-=-e-e(xo-yi)-, i £{1,...,n}, (4.18)

where pi = -(pi/po) v(x* - yh e) and Yie = -(Pi/P1)(yi/y1)(y1 - Vi)v(y1 - yi, e) using the abbreviation yi = Li - xi > 0.

Full Coverage. One immediate solution of (4.18) is yi = Li xi — x0, for all i £ {1,..., n}, which yields full coverage for the participating agent types.19 The lowest participating type eo in the full-coverage scenario is determined by setting that agent's insurance premium equal to his "certainty equivalent." The latter corresponds to the agent's compensating variation for the insurance contract, so necessarily xo = C (L1 - xo,...,Ln - xo, eo), which in turn implies that

{ ln(-r(eo))/«o, if eo £ (0,1],

xo = g(<W = \ L, if eo = 0,

where L = ^n=1 P.L. denotes the agent's expected loss.2° The principal's expected payoff under full coverage is F(x; eo) = (xo - L)(1 - F(eo)), so that the optimal participation threshold becomes the global solution of a scalar maximization problem on an interval (for details, see [18]):

e* £ arg max {(g(«o) - L)(1 - F(«o))} . eoe[o,1]

As a result, the optimal (constant) schedule is x* = (xo, L1 - x\,... ,Ln - xn), where xo = g(e*) and x* = Li - xo for i £ {1,... ,n}. The full-coverage solution leads to no information revelation at all, as all the agent types are offered the same contract. This is also referred to as "bunching" [4].

Partial Coverage. Based on the available optimality conditions it may be possible to construct another solution to the optimal insurance problem, which involves at least partial information revelation. Indeed, for a given 9 € (0,1], provided that ¡i = 0 and 0(9) = p0f(9)/0o(9) > 1/9, there is a negative solution to (4.18), i.e., there exists a Z = Z(9) < 0 such that

Z = {eez - l) (4.19)

In this case, the solution Z = %o — Vi = x0 + Xi — Li < 0 is independent of i € {1,...,n}. For 0( 9) € [0,1/9], the only solution to (4.19) is Z = 0, reverting back to the full-insurance regime (for that agent type 9). Because by the transversality condition (C1) it is 0o(1) = 0 , this implies that for large enough agent types 9 the principal may find it optimal to use partial coverage.

We now continue to follow the solution algorithm outlined in Remark 3, via (3.1) and (3.9). Indeed, the law of motion in (3.1), together with Xi = Z — X0 for all i € {1,..., n}, implies that

n 1—Po v(Z 9) Z !-P0 Z

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

Xo = ^ 9) ■ (x1,...,x„) = (Z — Xo) £ Pi(x, 9) = — 1 V(Z 9) = . (42°)

i=l 1 po 9) e + Po

19By the adjoint equation (C1), it is = (1 — F)p0 and = —(1 — F)pi on [9q, 1] for all i € {1,..., n}. (Thus, nontriviality (C5) holds.) Theorem 3 yields ¡(9) = ^0(9)p1 (x* (9), 9) + 01(9) = 0 for all 9 € [9^, 1].

20By l'Hôpital's rule and the definition of r, it is lim0o^o+ ln(— r(90))/90 = r'(0)/r(0) = L.

Using again the law of motion, the first component of the adjoint equation (3.9) becomes V-0 Pof . , , m x , . 9v(Z,

■— = — + (<Px(x, 0)u)o = 0 +--

^0 ^0 Po

-^ = V-f + (<px(x, 9)u)o = 0 + Epu = 0 - (4.21)

i=1

Since on the one hand = (f/f) — (0/0), by the definition of 0, and since on the other hand

0 = (1 — ) Z +

_ Ç + Ce9C

0 V ) z + 1 - '

by virtue of (4.19), one obtains—taking account of (4.20)—that relation (4.21) is equivalent to

f 0 . + ^ ( , He"-) z z 9Z

—-f = —0 +0 — 9x0 = "l.1+1 — 1 — ^ 1 +—

But the last equation implies an initial-value problem,

z =

1 + 9eez (1 - po)9 ] 1

Z + 1 - eÖZ + (1 - po) + Poe°z_

(L \

\f 1 - e^)

^ e8C,, Z (9o) = Co, (4.22)

where the initial value is equal to the certainty equivalent of the marginal agent's exposure conditional on a loss,21

c° =--d-<

thus rendering the contract worthless for the type 90, and consequently: x0(90) = 0.

5. Conclusion

The solution to multiattribute screening problems with one-dimensional types and type-dependent participation constraints can be obtained using optimality conditions derived from a nonstandard version of Pontryagin's maximum principle.22 Contrary to the extant literature on screening, we do not assume representations of preferences that are quasilinear in the numeraire attribute, thus allowing for arbitrary risk profiles. We also do not require payoff functions to be supermodular in all nonmonetary attributes but impose incentive compatibility as a nonlocal constraint. We have shown that a solution to the multiattribute screening problem, in the case where the incentive-compatibility constraint is binding, can be obtained by solving a sequence of relaxed screening problems, in which constraint violations are increasingly penalized. The results depend in essence only on the convexity of the participation set23 and on (local) incentive regularity (where needed). Thus, even if A1-A2 and P1-P2 are not satisfied everywhere, one may use our results to construct solutions and then verify the assumptions in a neighborhood of the obtained solutions ex post. We further show that the dimensionality of the 2(n + 1)-dimensional Hamiltonian system can often be reduced significantly in concrete problems (e.g., to a 1-dimensional differential equation in our optimal-insurance application in Section 4).

21The agent's expected utility is U(x, 9) = p0v(—x0, 9)+(1 — p0)v(Z—x0, 9) = (po + (1 — p0)e-p^) v(—x0, 9).

22 Type-dependent participation constraints arise when agents have heterogeneous outside options, as illustrated in Section 4.

23If U — r is quasiconcave in 9 (instead of nondecreasing) the participation set is of the form [90, 91] and 91 becomes subject to optimization, leading to an additional transversality condition analogous to C3.

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank Sergey Aseev and Arkardy Kryazhimskiy, as well as participants of the 2015 INFORMS Annual Meeting in Philadelphia and the 5th International Conference on Continuous Optimization (ICCOPT 2016) in Tokyo, for helpful discussions on related research. A number of very useful comments by an anonymous referee, Ksenia Melnikova, and participants of the 2016 International Conference on "System Analysis: Modeling and Control" in Yekaterinburg are gratefully acknowledged. This paper is dedicated to the memory of Academician Arkady Kryazhimskiy, an outstanding researcher and very kind individual, who will be missed.

REFERENCES

1. Mirrlees, J.A. An exploration in the theory of optimal income taxation // Rev. Econ. Stud. 1971. Vol. 38, no. 2, P. 175-208.

2. Baron, D.P., Myerson, R.B. Regulating a monopolist with unknown costs // Econometrica. 1982. Vol. 50, no. 4, P. 911-930.

3. Mirman, L.J., Sibley, D. Optimal nonlinear prices for multiproduct monopolies // Bell J. Econ. 1980. Vol. 11, no. 2, P. 659-670.

4. Mussa, M., Rosen, S. Monopoly and product quality // J. Econ. Theory. 1978. Vol. 18, no. 2, P. 301-317.

5. Guesnerie, R., Laffont, J.-J. A complete solution to a class of principal-agent problems with an application to the control of a self-managed firm // J. Public Econ. 1984. Vol. 25, no. 3, P. 329-369.

6. Matthews, S., Moore, J. Monopoly provision of quality and warranties: an exploration in the theory of multidimensional screening // Econometrica. 1987. Vol. 55, no. 2, P. 441-467.

7. Pontryagin, L.S., Boltyanskii, V.G., Gamkrelidze, R.V., Mishchenko, E.F. The mathematical theory of optimal processes, New York: Wiley Interscience, 1962. 360 p.

8. Aseev, S. Methods of regularization in nonsmooth problems of dynamic optimization // J. Math. Sci.

1999. Vol. 94, no. 3, P. 1366-1393.

9. Hicks, J.R. Value and capital, Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1939. 331 p.

10. Weber, T.A. Hicksian welfare measures and the normative endowment effect // Am. Econ. J.: Microecon. 2010. Vol. 2, no. 4, P. 171-194.

11. Weber, T.A. Screening with externalities. Working Paper, Stanford University, 2005.

12. Gibbard, A. Manipulation of voting schemes: a general result // Econometrica. 1973. Vol. 41, no. 4, P. 587-601.

13. Myerson, R.B. Incentive compatibility and the bargaining problem // Econometrica. 1979. Vol. 47, no. 1, P. 61-74.

14. Rudin, W. Principles of mathematical analysis (3rd edition). New York: McGraw-Hill, 1976. 342 p.

15. Jayne, J.E., Rogers, C.A. Selectors. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2002. 167 p.

16. Laffont, J.-J. The economics of uncertainty and information. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989. 289 p.

17. Stiglitz, J.E. Monopoly, non-linear pricing and imperfect information: the insurance market // Rev. Econ. Stud. 1977. Vol. 44, no. 3, P. 407-430.

18. Weber, T.A. Global optimization on an interval // J. Optimiz. Theory App. 2016. Forthcoming. [doi:10.1007/s10957-016-1006-y]

19. Arutyunov, A.V. Optimality conditions: abnormal and degenerate problems. Dordrecht: Kluwer,

2000. 299 p.

20. Weber, T.A. Optimal control theory with applications in economics. Cambridge: MIT Press, 2011. 360 p. (Preface by A.V. Kryazhimskiy)

21. Gelfand, I.M., Fomin, S.V. Calculus of variations. Englewood-Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, 1963. 240 p.

22. Kolmogorov, A.N., Fomin, S.V. Elements of the theory of functions and functional analysis, parts I & II. Rochester: Graylock Press, 1957. 288 p.

23. Megginson, R.E. An introduction to Banach space theory. New York: Springer, 1998. 596 p.

24. Dunford, N., Schwartz, J.T. Linear operators, part I: general theory. New York: Wiley Interscience, 1958. 858 p.

25. Milyutin, A.A., Osmolovskii, N.P. Calculus of variations and optimal control. Providence: American Mathematical Society, 1998. 372 p.

26. Zorich, V.A. Mathematical analysis, vol. I. New York: Springer, 2004. 574 p.

27. Kirillov, A.A., Gvishiani, A.D. Theorems and problems in functional analysis. New York: Springer, 1982. 347 p.

28. Taylor, A.E. General theory of functions and integration. New York: Blaisdell Publishing, 1965. 437 p.

29. Giaquinta, M., Modica, G., SouCek, J. Cartesian currents in the calculus of variations, vol. I. New York: Springer, 1998. 711 p.

30. Riesz, F., Sz.-Nagy, B. Functional analysis, New York: Ungar Publishing, 1955. 491 p.

31. Schechter, M. Principles of functional analysis (2nd edition). Providence: American Mathematical Society, 2002. 425 p.

Appendix: Proof of Theorem 2

Proof. The argument proceeds in six steps (cf. [7,8,19,20]). For any (x, 9) € Rn+1 x 0, let

g(x, 9) = min {(9 - 9) (ug(x*(9), 9) - Ue(x, 9)

êp&ï y- V '

Step 1: Approximate the problem (P) by a sequence of relaxed problems {(Pk)} .

We approximate the principal's screening problem (P) by a sequence of problems (Pk), k = 1,2,..., in each of which the constraints are relaxed. The sequence of relaxed problems approximates the original problem, since deviations from the constraints and the optimal control u* are penalized using successively increasing weights. We first fix the positive numbers e, S, and

U > 2 + ess sup ||u*(9)||,

eee*0

relative to which the sequence {(Pk)}£= of relaxed problems will be defined. For any k > 1, let

Vk(x, u, 9) = V(x, 9) - S||u(9) - u*(9)||2 - kg_(x, 9)2, (5.1)

where g_ = min{g, 0} takes on nonzero (negative) values whenever the relevant constraint (3.2) of the original problem (P) is violated. Similarly, for any 90 € 0 and x € R++1 we set

K(x, 9o) = (min{9o, 0})2 + (U(x, 9o) - r(9o))2 (5.2)

to penalize deviations from the endpoint constraints (including 0 > 0) imposed in the original problem. We are now ready to formulate the relaxed problem (Pk) for any k > 1, given an optimal solution (x* ,u*, 9*) €D to the original problem (P):

' sup(x^0x)€D { /¡0 Vk(x(9),u(9), 9) dF( 9) - (x - x*)2 - (9o - 9*)2 - kK(x,

<

(x, u, 00 ,x)£D

s.t.

x = x(90) = x,

£ > ||x - x * + (x - x*)2 + (9o - 9*)2 u,

(P fc )

where DD = V x R++1 is an augmented domain of admissibility, U = {U € 1" : ||U|| < u} is a control-constraint set, and x* = x*(9g) is the bundle offered to the optimal marginal agent type. We denote a solution to the relaxed problem (Pk) by (xk,uk ,90k ,xk). By setting uk to zero for all 9 € [90k, 1] we extend any such solution to all types in 0 (containing the optimal interval [90k, 1]), so the state trajectory xk is constant on [0, 90k].

Step 2: Show that each problem (Pk) has a solution. For any k > 1, there exists a solution (xk,uk,9$,xk) to the relaxed problem (Pk). Let

{(xkj ,ukj ,9 k'j ,xk'j )}"=

be an admissible maximizing sequence [21, p. 193] for the problem (Pk). Since uk,j takes values in the closed ball of 1" at 0 of radius u, and a forteriori the contract space (which contains all bundles that can actually be transacted between principal and agent) is bounded by T1,24 this maximizing sequence is uniformly bounded, which allows the following three conclusions for an appropriate subsequence (and for simplicity we identify our original maximizing sequence with this subsequence by relabelling indices if necessary). First, from the definition of an admissible sequence {xkj}«=1 c W1q and the uniform boundedness of {xk,j this sequence of state trajectories is equicontinuous, so by the Arzela—Ascoli theorem [22, Part I, p. 54] it converges uniformly to xk. Second, we obtain pointwise convergence of (xk,j, 9k'j) to (xk, 9k) as j — to. Third, since the space of admissible controls Lq is a subset of the Hilbert space L2 (which can be identified with its dual),

u

k,j

25

converges weakly to uk as j — to. We now show that in fact the above limits coincide with the solution to (Pk), i.e.,

(xk ,uk,9%,xk ) = (Xk,Xk ,9k,Xk ).

(5.3)

For any 9 e [9k, 1] it is

z" (9)

so by taking the limit for j — to:

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

kj (9) — xkj ( 9k,j

'0

) + / $(xk'j(0),0)ukj (0) d0

xk(9)— xk(Xk) + / $(xk(0),0)uk(0) dé.

Hence, the limiting tuple (xk ,uk ,9$ ,xk) is consistent with the Cauchy problem for the state evolution, i.e., it satisfies

xk — $uk

k Xk

Xk_x*

) = xk.

+ (9$ — 9g) is satisfied by uniform con-

The state constraint e > \\xk — x* yqq +

vergence of the maximizing sequence. Lastly, the control constraint uk € U is satisfied, since each uk'j, j = 1,2,..., is feasible (u has been chosen appropriately large). The weak convergence uk,j uk as j — to implies, by Mazur's compactness theorem [23, p. 254], that there exists a sequence {vk,j }°=1 with elements in the convex hull co {uk,j }°=1 which converges strongly to uk in L"(0). We therefore obtain that equation (5.3) holds, i.e., the limit point (xk,uk,9k,xk) of the maximizing sequence describes an admissible solution to the relaxed problem (Pk).

Step 3: Show that the solutions of (Pk)k>1 converge to the solution of (P).

As before, there exists an admissible tuple (x, u, 90) € D such that xk ^ xk

u

k w

We now show that

U, and 9k — X

Xk

.

(x, U, 90) — (x*,u* ,9*),

(5.4)

i.e., in particular that xk ^ x*, uk -— u*, and 9k — 9

24The assumption T1 is used here to guarantee the boundedness of the first (numeraire) component of the attribute schedule, as its dynamics in (3.1) are not directly governed by the control variable.

25By the Banach—Alaoglu theorem the unit ball in L2 is weakly* (and therefore weakly) compact, so by the Eberlein—Smulian theorem it is also weakly sequentially compact [23, p. 229/248]. This property of reflexive Banach spaces can also be deduced from the uniform boundedness principle [24, Ch. 2].

e

9

0

9

2

Let nk(x,u,9o,x) = fgo Vk(x(9),u(9),9) dF(9) - ||x -x*||2 - (9o - 9*)2 - kK(x,9o). As a consequence of the uniform boundedness of the state-control trajectories, there exists a constant M > 0 such that M > nk(xk,uk,9k,xk) for all k. Since nk(xk,uk,9k,xk) - nk(x*,u*,9*,x*) > 0, it is

f > (£) Uuk - u*||2 + g2) dF(9) + ( [||xk - x* ||2 + 9 - 9*)2] + K(xk,9k) > 0.

Taking the limit for k — to, by continuity of K it is K(x, 9o) = 0, i.e., (x, 9o) satisfies the endpoint constraints U(x, 9o) = r(9o) and 9o > 0. Moreover,

lim f (g_(xk, 9))2 dF(9) = 0.

J0k

Since the type distribution F has full support 0 (no type can be excluded for sure), it is

g_(xk ,9) = 0.

Hence, g(xk,9) = 0, which is equivalent to

(9 >9 ^ Ue(x*(9), 9) > Ue(xk(9), 9), \9 < 9 ^ Ue(x*(9), 9) < Ue(xk(9), 9),

for all 9, 9 € 0. Because U is by assumption twice differentiable, and Ue(x, 9) is Lipschitz-continuous in x, there exists a constant L > 0 such that \Ue(x,9) - Ue(y,9)\ < L^x - yW for all x,y in the relevant (by assumption T1 bounded) contract space ^ and all 9 € 0. For 9 >9 this means that

Ue(xk(9), 9) + LUx* - xkH > Ue(xk(9), 9) + (U(x*(9),9) - Ue(xk(9), 9)} > Ue(xk(9), 9),

and, for 9 <9, that

Ue(xk(9), 9) - LUx* - xkm > Ue(xk(9), 9) + (U(x*(9),9) - Ue(xk(9), 9)) < Ue(xk(9), 9).

Hence, it is

min {(9 - 9) (Ue(x*(9),9) - Ue(x*(9),9)U > -Le,

and for e — 0+ the limit (x,u,9o,x) becomes admissible in problem (P). This implies

n(x*,u*, 9*,x*) > n(x, u, 9o, x). (5.5)

On the other hand, nk(xk,uk,9k,xk) > nk(x*, u*, 9*, x*) =: n(x*,u*,9*,x*) = V(x*; 9*), whence

n(xk,uk,9k,xk) - !xk - x*||2 - (9k - 9*)2 - S f !uk - u*||2 dF(9) > n(x*,u*,9*,x*)

Jek

for all k > 1. Hence, taking the limit for k — to yields

n(x,u,x,9o) - (9o - 9*0)2 - S lim [ !uk - u*||2 dF(9) > n(x*,u*,9*0,x*),

\ J k^J Qo

which together with (5.5) implies that 9o = 9*, u = u*, and

lim / !uk - u* ||2 dF(9) = 0,

JQ

so the sequence {uk converges to u* a.e. on 0.

Step 4-' Show that the problem (Pk) becomes a standard OCP (P'k) for large k. Because of the uniform convergence of the optimal state-trajectories xk and the pointwise convergence of the boundary points 9k (as k — to) to the corresponding optimal state trajectory x* and optimal boundary point 9* of the original problem (P), the state constraint in the relaxed problem (Pk) is strictly not binding for large enough k, i.e.,

e> \\xk — x* \\^o + (9kk — 9*)2,

as long as k is sufficiently large. Hence, for fixed constants e, S, and U there exists a k0 = k0(e, S, u) > 1 such that for all k > k0 the problem (Pk) can be rewritten equivalently in the form

sup^ u x)D { /¡0 Vk(x(9),u(9), 9) dF(9) — \\x — x* \\2 — (9„ — 9*)2 — kK(x, 9q)} 1 s.t. ' ' '(Pk) x = $u, x(90 ) = x. )

Necessary optimality conditions based on the maximum principle [7] for problem (P'k) are readily available.

Step 5: Obtain necessary optimality conditions for (Pk). We provide here a version of the maximum principle by Milyutin and Osmolovskii [25, P. 24-25].26 Let

Hk(x, u, 9, Xk,ïk) = XkVkf + ïk • $u

be the Hamiltonian function associated with problem (P'k), where Xk G R is a constant multiplier, ïk g Rn+1 is an adjoint variable, and x is the state of the system. The Hamiltonian corresponds to the instantaneous payoff to the principal including the current benefit of state velocities. The shadow prices of these are measured by the adjoint variables X^ and ïk respectively.

Maximum Principle for Problem (P'k). If (xk,uk,9k,xk) is an optimal solution for the problem (Pk), then there exists an absolutely continuous function ïk : [9k, 1] — Rn+1, and a constant Xk > 0, such that the following relations hold.

1. Adjoint Equation:

—ïk(9) = Hk(xk(9),uk(9), 9, Xk,ïk(9)) (5.6)

2. State Transversality:

ïk(9k) = 2k (U(xk,9k) — r(9k)) Ux(xk,9k) + 2 (xk — x*) (5.7)

ïk (1) = 0 (5.8)

3. Maximality:

uk(9) G argmaxHk(xk(9),u,9,X$,ïk(9)) a.e. on [9k, 1] (5.9)

u^U

One can extend the standard maximum principle comprised by the above conditions, and obtain the following type-transversality condition.

4. Type Transversality:

{ 2 (k min{9k, 0} + k (U(xk,9k) — r(9k)) (Ue(xk,9k) — r(9k)) + (9k — 9*)) } 1 +supu€M Hk (xk ,u,9k ,Xk ,ïk (9k)) = 0. f (.)

26They consider a slightly more general Mayer problem. Problem (Pk) is a Bolza problem on a variable interval, which can be reduced to a Mayer problem (in which the objective function depends only on the endpoints of the state trajectory) by introducing an additional real-valued state variable.

The type-transversality condition is crucial for determining the missing multiplier associated with the optimization of the participation set in the principal's screening problem. To prove type transversality, consider some real т (with \т\ sufficiently small), and let

л k (т ) = (xk (в k+т ),ek+т ),

and

Пk(т) = f XkVk(xk(в),ик(в), в) dF(в) - ||o)k(т) - (x*,&*)H2 - kK(ûк(т)),

Jek+T

where if necessary we extend the state-control trajectory beyond the lowest participating type. Then by optimality of в k,

о < пk (0) - nk (т)

r ek+T

= XkVk(xk,uk,в) dF(в)+ (^(т) - (х*,в*)||2 - H(xk - x*,ek - в*)||2)

Je*

+k (K(шк(т)) - K(xk,ek))

e+T

(XkVk f + (2 (xk (в) - x*) + kKx(xk(в), в)) ■ xk (в) + 2(в - в*0) + kKe0 (xk (в), в)) dв

rek+T / )

= / ^ [Hk (xk, uk ,9, Xk X) lk=2(xk (e)-x.)+kKx(xk (.),.) + K (xk (9), 9)) d0 + 29 — 9*)t + t 2

r e0+t ( \

< sup Hk(xk,u,9,Xk, 2 (xk — x*) + kKx(xk,9)) + kK6o (xk(9),9) d9 + 2(9k — 9*)t + t2.

Jek \ueu J

By the first mean-value theorem for the integral [26, p. 352], the last integral can be written in the form

(sup Hk (x(9k ),u,0k X, 2 (xk (9k) — x*) + kKx(xk (9Sk ),9k)) + kKoo (xk(0k ),9k)) t

\ueU )

for some appropriate 9!k € 9,9k + t]. Hence, dividing the previous inequality by t > 0 and subsequently taking the limit for t — 0+ yields

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

0 < sup Hk(xk, и, в, X0, 2 (xk - x*) + kKx(xk, )) + kKdo (xk, вк) + 2(вк - в*0). (5.11)

пШ ^ '

Consider now the case where we extend the type interval by an increment T > 0 to the left beyond the optimal lowest type 9k, which corresponds to t < 0 in the above relations. If we set t = —t> 0, then it is (using our earlier computations)

0 <-[° ( Hk (xk ,uk ,вX ,^k) + kKe0 (xk (в),вЛ dв—2(в¡k-в0*)г+г2,

" Jek_f V Xk = 2(xk(e)-x*)+kKx(xk(0)fi) 0K ') 0 07

where we can extend uk(9), for all 9 € [9k — r,9k] to the left. In particular, the latter extension can be performed such that

P >

sup Hk xk ,и,вХ ,kKx(xk (в),в)) - Hk xk ,uk ,вХ ,kKx(xk (в), в))

ueu

on the interval [в k - f, вk] for some arbitrary p > 0. Hence,

0 < - (sup Hk (xk (0k),u,0k ,Xk, 2 (xk в ) - x* ) + kKx(xk в )в )) - P + K (xk(0k ),вk ) +2(вk - в*)) f+f2

\ueu )

ek

eo

for some 90* € [90*—f, 90*}, so by dividing through f > 0 and taking the limits for f ^ 0+ and p ^ 0+, we get

0 > sup Hk(xk,u, 90k, Ak, 2 (xk - x*) + kKx(xk, 9k)) + kK0o(xk, 9k) + 2(9£ - 9*0). (5.12)

u&U ^ '

Relations (5.11) and (5.12), together with (5.7), are equivalent to (5.10).

Using the above extended maximum principle (5.6)-(5.10) for the relaxed problem (P*), one obtains the adjoint equation

—0* = X**Vxf + v*gx + 0* • ($xu*) = X**Vxf + v*gx + 0k*pxu* (5.13)

on 0, where

v*(9) i —2kX*g-(x*, 9), 9 € [90*, 1}, (5 14)

v ' | 0, otherwise. v ' '

The maximality condition (5.9) constitutes a constrained optimization problem, for which there exists a Lagrange multiplier q* = q* (9) such that

+ — 2X* 5(u* — u*) + 2q * u* = 0

for all i € {1,...,n}, with complementary slackness q* ([[u* || — u) =0. By Step 3 we know that u* ^ u* a.e. on 0. Hence, by Egorov's theorem [27, p. 24} for any 5 > 0 there is a subset 0u of 0, such that /Q\Q_ d9 < 5 and u* ^ u* uniformly on 0j. Since u* is feasible, this uniform

convergence implies that u* € dU on 0u for k large enough. By virtue of complementary slackness, the corresponding Lagrange multipliers q* and p* therefore vanish on 0g, as long as k is large enough. In other words,

+ 0 — 2X** 5(u* — u * )=0 (5.15)

a.e. on 0 for all i € {1,..., n}, as long as k is large enough.

Step 6: Derive necessary optimality conditions for (P). The sequence {X*is uniformly bounded and {0*is also equicontinuous. Hence we conclude, as before (in Step 2), that there exist 0£u and Xs,u, such that

0* ^ 0S,u, X** ^ Xs,u.

As already indicated through the notation, the limits 0s,u and Xs,u generically depend on the constants 5 and u. More specifically, these limits correspond to the optimal solution to the screening problem (P) if we replace V by V — 5||u — u* ||2 and introduce the additional constraint ||u|| < u.

Adjoint Equation. Since by the maximum principle for problem (P*) (cf. Step 5) it is X* > 0, relations (5.6)-(5.8) are positively homogeneous of degree one in 0*/Xl*, and relation (5.9) is positively homogeneous of degree zero, it is possible to multiply equations (5.6)-(5.8) with positive numbers (and relabel the variables X* and 0* back), such that

0 <X** + max H0*(9)||2 + [ (v*(9))2 d9 < 1. (5.16)

oe[o0U1] Jok

Integrating the components of the adjoint equation (5.13) yields (using the state-transversality condition (5.8))

0*(9) = / (X**Vxf + 0**Pxu*) d9 +/ v*gxd9 (5.17)

Jo Jo

for all 9 € 0 (using the standard extension from [9*, 1} to 0 explained in Step 1).

Consider now a Borel measure with density given vk by (5.14).27 By abuse of notation we denote this measure also by vk. The Borel measure vk is nonnegative by construction and bounded as a consequence of (5.16). Thus, there exists a Borel measure v, such that (passing to a subsequence if necessary) vk -— v as k — to.

Since the total variation of 0k on © is uniformly bounded for all k by (5.16) (for every absolutely continuous function is of bounded variation on a compact interval [28, p. 412]), and the sequence {0k} is also uniformly bounded as a consequence of (5.17), by Helly's selection principle [28, p. 398] there exists a function ip, so (a subsequence of) the sequence {0k} converges to ip. By taking the limit in (5.17) for k — to we thus obtain

0x(Q)=/ (XoVxf + ip ■ $*) dQ + /" gxdv, (5.18)

J & J &

for almost all Q € ©0, where ip = s. The adjoint equation C1 then follows by noting that (using the envelope theorem) gx(x*(d),d) = - (p(x*(d),d) - Q) Ux&(x*(Q),Q).

Maximality. Consider the maximality condition (5.15) for Problem (Pk), which holds for k large enough. Since xk ^ x* and uk — u* (a.e. on ©) for k — to, we obtain the maximality condition C2.

Transversality. Since Q0k — Q* as k tends to infinity (cf. Step 3), by setting

Ai = - lim 2k (U(xk,Qk) - r(Qk)) and A2 = - lim 2k min{Q£, 0}

k^tt k^tt

we obtain from the state-transversality condition (5.7) for k — to (taking into account the maxi-mality condition C2) that

0(Q*) = -AiUx(x *,Q*), (5.19)

and from the type transversality condition (5.10) that

-Ai (U&(x*,Q*) - r(Q*)) - A2 + A 0V(x *,Q*) = 0. (5.20)

If Q* > 0, then by the definition of A2 it is A2 = 0. Combining relations (5.19) and (5.20) for A2 = 0 yields the transversality condition C3 (ii). If on the other hand Q* = 0, then we obtain the transversality condition C3 (i) from relation (5.19) directly.

27Recall [29, Ch. 1] that all Borel measures v on © form a linear normed space with norm

\\vII = sup i h(ti) dv(■&).

heC[ 0,1]:||h||„ = 1 J 0

Interpreting the above Stieltjes integral as a scalar product, we can think of any Borel measure v as an element of the dual space (C[0,1])*. A sequence of Borel measures v1, v2,... weak * -converges to v if for all h e C[0,1],

i h(&) dvk (■&) — i h(&) dv(&),

Jo Jo

as k — to. Since C[0,1] is separable, by the theorem of choice every (bounded) sequence of measures has a weak * -convergent subsequence [30, p. 64; 31, p. 189]. Since for any h e C[0,1] the function J® h($) dv(d) is continuous a.e. on ©, for any sequence of points {0k}^=1 with limit 0, for almost every such 0 e © it is:

lim / h($) dv($) = h(&) dv(-d). J0 J0

Moreover, if in addition the sequence {vk}£=0 of Borel measures has the Borel measure v as its limit, then

e

lim / h(ê) dvk(iï) = h(ê) dv(ê) J0 J0

for almost every 0 e ©.

Complementary Slackness. The definition (5.14) of the measure vk, and the fact that vk -— v as k — to (cf. also footnote 27) yields the complementary slackness condition C4.

Nontriviality. If X0 and ^ are trivial, then (X 0,^) must vanish identically on 0*. From the adjoint equation C1 it follows that

[ gx(x*(&),#) dv('d) = 0 Je

for all 9 € 0*. By the complementary slackness condition C4, whenever v(9) = 0 it is also g(x*(9),9) = 0. This implies that

dv = 0.

Jeo

On the other hand, it is possible to renormalize the middle term in (5.16) in the solution of the approximate problem (Pk) such that

Xk + max Uk(9)||2 + + (vk(9))2 d9 = 1

ee[ej,i] Jek

for any k > 1. By taking the limit for k — to,

f (v(9))2 d9 = 1.

e o

By the nonnegativity of the measure v, this yields a contradiction. Hence, the incentive regularity condition A3 ensures that (X 0,^) does not vanish identically on the optimal participation set 0*, which implies the nontriviality condition C5. □

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.