Научная статья на тему 'Monotowns: a quantitative analysis'

Monotowns: a quantitative analysis Текст научной статьи по специальности «Экономика и бизнес»

CC BY
215
51
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
Журнал
Baltic Region
Scopus
RSCI
ESCI
Область наук
Ключевые слова
MONOTOWN / SINGLE INDUSTRY TOWN / INSTITUTIONAL AGREEMENT / CLUSTER ANALYSIS / INFORMATION ASYMMETRY

Аннотация научной статьи по экономике и бизнесу, автор научной работы — Shastitko Andrei, Fatikhova Adelya

The authors propose an empirical analysis of the current situation in monotowns. The study questions the perceived seriousness of the ‘monotown problem’ as well as the actual challenges it presents. The authors use cluster analysis to divide monotowns into groups for further structural comparison. Since structural differences in the available databases limit the possibilities of empirical analysis, alternative approaches are required; the authors consider possible reasons for the limitations identified. Special attention is paid to the monotowns that have been granted the status of advanced development territories. Comparative analysis makes it possible to study their general characteristics and socioeconomic indicators. The authors apply the theory of opportunistic behaviour to describe potential problems caused by the lack of unified criteria for granting monotowns the status of advanced development territories. The article identifies the main stakeholders and the nature of their interaction; it describes a conceptual model built on the principal-agent interactions, and draws a possible scenario of mutually beneficial cooperation. The solution to the principal-agent problem suggested in the article contributes to the development of an alternative approach to the current situation and a rational approach to overcoming the ‘monotown problem’.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.

Текст научной работы на тему «Monotowns: a quantitative analysis»

ECONOMICS

Lomonosov Moscow State University 1 Leninskie Gory, Moscow, 119991 Russia

Russian Presidential Academy of National Economy and Public Administration 84 prospekt Vernadskogo, Moscow, 119571 Russia

Submitted on March 18, 2016. doi: 10.5922/2079-8555-2016-2-1 © Shastitko A., Fatikhova A., 2016

The authors propose an empirical analysis of the current situation in monotowns. The study questions the perceived seriousness of the 'monotown problem' as well as the actual challenges it presents. The authors use cluster analysis to divide monotowns into groups for further structural comparison. Since structural differences in the available databases limit the possibilities of empirical analysis, alternative approaches are required; the authors consider possible reasons for the limitations identified. Special attention is paid to the monotowns that have been granted the status of advanced development territories. Comparative analysis makes it possible to study their general characteristics and socioeconomic indicators. The authors apply the theory of opportunistic behaviour to describe potential problems caused by the lack of unified criteria for granting mono-towns the status of advanced development territories. The article identifies the main stakeholders and the nature of their interaction; it describes a conceptual model built on the principal-agent interactions, and draws a possible scenario of mutually beneficial cooperation. The solution to the principal-agent problem suggested in the article contributes to the development of an alternative approach to the current situation and a rational approach to overcoming the 'monotown problem'.

Key words: monotown, single industry town, institutional agreement, cluster analysis, information asymmetry

Introduction

Issues pertaining to managing monotowns by way of either ensuring their viability or choosing a different development path are becoming increasing relevant. While this phenomenon is often perceived as an exclusively Russian

Baltic region. 2016. Vol. 8, № 2. P. 4—19.

problem, it became the focus of public attention in other countries much earlier than in Russia. Already in the 1960s, the US and some European countries were looking for different solutions to socioeconomic problems of monotowns [21]. In Russia, special attention to the monotown problem is determined by the general conditions of socioeconomic development, with the 2008—2009 crisis being a vivid example. In this period, the country witnessed growing willingness to protests among the general public and an increased attention to monotowns from politicians and mass media, as well as resumed construction of new factories [4]. Yet a comprehensive assessment of the monotown situation is hindered by the lack of relevant information. Despite the availability of a regularly updated governmental list of mono-towns, most of the data necessary for a high-quality analysis is difficult to obtain, and statistics provided by Rosstat (Federal State Statistics Servise), whose online database is often used to assess the conditions and prospects of socioeconomic development of monotowns, is hardly sufficient. This does not mean that we cannot advance in empirical studies. This article aims to propose approaches to a quantitative analysis of socioeconomic situation in monotowns, based on available information and taking into account incentives to rent-seeking behaviour.

The structure of the paper is as follows. The first part of the article describes elements of cluster analysis as applied to a monotown sample in view of the existing information limitations. The second part focuses on variables and the results of clustering. The third part considers development problems of monotowns as advanced development territories in the context of rentseeking behaviour. Key results are summarised in the conclusion.

1. An approach to cluster analysis of monotowns

At first, the authors of this article attempted to address the socioeconomic situation in monotowns using the cluster analysis. Monotown clusters with similar structure were to be identified based on a statistical data analysis, followed by the development of a special approach to examining the situation in each cluster. However, in practice, an analysis of statistical data proved rather complicated. In April 2015, the list of monotowns was extended once again [13] and its structure changed. All monotowns were now divided into three categories. Each included both large cities with a population of over 500,000 people and small villages with several thousand residents. But is such classification justified? Does it allow us to take into account all structurally significant factors?

In keeping with the initial homogeneity criterion1, it was decided to analyse qualitative characteristics of monotowns in the first category, i. e. those most sensitive to socioeconomic changes. The following parameters were chosen as benchmarks.

1 The homogeneity criterion is understood as monotowns retaining their positions in initial categories. However, there is a possibility that monotowns can be further classed within each of the three categories. If further classification is possible, an analysis will be simplified, since it will become possible to choose a methodology for managing monotown risks.

1. Fixed assets investment — expenditure on buildings and other means of production. This parameter should be taken into account, since the risk of principal employer's facilities becoming obsolete is widely discussed in literature. It would be interesting to understand whether fixed asset investment (in the context of building) affects the balance sheet of a municipality2.

2. Local budget revenues, including non-repayable receipts — a parameter determining the potential size of funds transferred to a municipality for purposes and functions within the agent's competence. Using this parameter is necessitated by the fact that an assessment of the socioeconomic situation in a monotown requires information about the size of funds available to the municipality.

3. Personal income tax is a direct tax calculated as a percentage of the total income of persons, with due exemptions. This parameter should be used to compare monotowns based on expected income of residents.

4. Revenues from using public and municipal property are a parameter determining the revenue associated with the exploitation of public property. It is necessary for assessing the reasonableness of expenditure on putting property online.

5. Environmental damages are compensation for environmental pollution. Environmental risk is often mentioned as a risk associated with mono-towns. It is evident that monotowns, whose viability depends on the extraction industry, are more susceptible to this risk than those dominated by the processing industry3 are.

6. Municipal social policy spending is the part of municipal budget allocated to support the welfare of citizens. This parameter is included into the analysis to estimate expenditures on maintaining the required socioeconomic level.

7. Population is the number of citizens living in a monotown. This parameter should be taken into account in comparing the specific amount of expenditure in view of the population size.

Ninety tree first category monotowns were analysed using the SPSS analytics software. However, it was not possible to classify all 319 monotowns by cluster due to two reasons. Firstly, as mentioned above, it would be inappropriate to compare densely populated towns and villages with few thousand residents. Secondly, statistics available on official websites does not make it possible to form clusters for analysis — for instance, some of the Volga region towns regularly update statistics, whereas some Siberian towns present no information at all. Moreover, the incompleteness of available data complicates a panel analysis for the chosen period (2007—2014). At the same time, a panel analysis seems to be crucial, since the increased attention to the monotown problem observed in crisis periods requires assessing the similarity of monotowns' reactions to external shocks.

2 The authors realize that this parameter is not sufficient to demonstrate municipal expenditure on fixed asset maintenance. However, since the Rosstat website does not present any more appropriate data, it was decided to use this parameter adding an error function, when conducting a cluster analysis.

3 However, environmental risks are a significant threat in both types of monotowns.

Therefore, it would be logical to make the sample as homogeneous as possible to increase its qualitative representativeness and retain the possibility of checking its structural elements after clustering. It was decided to consider towns with a population of over 100,000 people. Generally, in such towns there are other employers, apart from the principal one. However, according to the governmental monotown list, they are divided into categories depending on the socioeconomic situation. Therefore, it is proposed to conduct a cluster analysis to estimate the homogeneity of characteristics underlying such a classification. If the towns comprising a cluster have similar characteristics, they should probably be monitored using a certain scheme. If it is not the case, it is important to consider the cause-effect relations behind the homogeneity divergences between towns belonging to one cluster both in model and in reality.

2. Description of variables and the analysis

23 towns were selected from the governmental list, based on the following criteria:

— a population of over 100,000 people;

— town statistics available at www. gks. ru in the Russian regions. Major socioeconomic indicators of towns — 2014 reference book.

The following variables were treated as explanatory variables (all variables were standardised during the analysis):

I stands for fixed assets investment. This variable is entered as an explanatory variable, since it reflects expenditure on reproducing fixed assets, which is especially relevant in the case of monotowns, where the depreciation of fixed assets and the absence of their reproduction remain major obstacles to the performance of monotowns' major employers.

F stands for the number of organisations engaged in manufacturing. This variable is included, since most monotowns specialise in extracting and/or manufacturing.

P stands for local population. This parameter is instrumental in detailing the scale of problems in a monotown. It also serves as a criterion for selecting monotowns for analysis (those with a population of over 100,000 people). It is evident that partial resettlement followed by economic diversification and relevant initiatives will be more probable and less painful to residents of a monotown with a population of approximately 100,000 people than in a monotown with that of over 200,000 residents.

L stands for working-age population. The variable is necessary for assessing performance potential in a monotown.

U is the number of non-working citizens registered with the employment office and officially recorded as unemployed. This variable is necessary for estimating the pressure on the welfare and social support system.

AS stands for average nominal gross salary (roubles). It is necessary for estimating the average monthly income of a monotown's population and identifying its principal industry.

Cr stands for the registered crime rate. This variable makes it possible to assess the level of potential socioeconomic tension in the town.

Cat is the category assigned to a monotown in the governmental list (1, 2, or 3).

Of course, these variables do not fully reflect the relevant aspects of socioeconomic situation in monotowns. It would be more practical to use the overall crime rate, since the registered crime rate can distort the actual picture. This is especially true in the cases when the ratio between the two types of crime is skewed towards unregistered ones. Another example is the nominal gross salary. This parameter is one of the most available for a quantitative assessment. However, it can hardly be used if one focuses on changes over time rather than those within a certain period. Moreover, a more accurate evaluation of this parameter requires understanding the extent of the effect of distorting factors — outside earnings and temporal consumption structure (i. e. changes in consumer debts).

After selecting variables using the SPSS analytics software, a cluster analysis yielded the following classification.

Cluster Town

Cluster 1 Neftekamsk

Dmitrovgrad

Novocheboksarsk

Severodvinsk

Kaspiysk

Nevinnomyssk

Belovo

Leninsk-Kuznetsky

Mezhdurechensk

Prokopyevsk

Kamensk-Uralsky

Pervouralsk

Serov

Zlatoust

Miass

Custer 2 Tolyatti

Novokuznetsk

Cluster 3 Naberezhnye Chelny

Cherepovets

Cluster 4 Nizhnekamsk

Cluster 5 Norilsk

Cluster 6 Nizhny Tagil

Magnitogorsk

Let us consider each of the clusters and try to understand whether the classification criteria match the reality.

Cluster 1

Cluster 1 towns divided into categories4:

Category 1 Category 2 Category 3

Kaspiysk Neftekamsk Dmitrovgrad

Prokopyevsk Nevinnomyssk Novocheboksarsk

Pervouralsk Belovo Severodvinsk

Leninsk-Kuznetsky Serov

Mezhdurechensk

Kamensk-Uralsky

Zlatoust

Miass

According to the database, towns belonging to category 1 of cluster 1 meet the following criteria:

Population of 105—202 thousand people.

Number of the employed ranging from 68 to 113 thousand people.

Fixed assets investment from 1,442 to 2,996 thousand roubles.

Average nominal gross salary from 17,283 to 26,357 roubles.

Category 2:

Population of 101—173.3 thousand people.

Number of the employed ranging from 57.4 to 97.9 thousand people.

Fixed assets investment from 842.5 to 11,629 thousand roubles.

Average nominal gross salary ranging from 21.693 to 33.416 roubles.

Category 3:

Population of 107.2—188.4 thousand people.

Number of the employed ranging from 61.3 to 112.3 thousand people.

Fixed assets investment from 4124.6 to 7328.1 thousand roubles.

Average nominal gross salary ranging from 20711.8 to 36983.4 roubles.

In general, monotowns constituting this cluster have similar characteristics. When analysing the monotowns by categories, one can see that there is no significant difference in values. Therefore, such classification can be built and applied in practice5. A general solution to the 'monotown problem' can be found at least for the cluster under consideration. In this case, one should answer the question as to what difference is significant and based on what criteria it can be acknowledged as such. Moreover, although the population of monotowns comprising the cluster, the number of the employed, and the

4 According to Governmental Decree 668-r of April 16, 2015, monotowns of the first category are characterised by the most difficult socioeconomic situation, the second by risks of the situation deteriorating, and the third by a stable socioeconomic situation.

5 It is possible to create a completely accurate classification due to structural flaws of explanatory variables. At least, when building a mode, some variables are used twice, for instance, if the population or the number of the employed are considered.

<p

average salary are comparable, fixed assets investment raises a number of question, For instance, in category 2 monotowns, it is even smaller than in category 1, although it should apparently be vice versa. Is this situation a result of production diversification in category 2 monotowns, which can be corroborated by smaller municipal expenditure on fixed assets reproduction? Is it a result of distorted statistics? It is also possible that some monotowns comprising category 2 would be classed as category 1 in the case of an alternative combination of socioeconomic factors?

Cluster 2

Cluster 2 is comprised of two towns — Tolyatti of category 2 and Novokuznetsk of category 1. The population of Tolyatti is 718 thousand people, whereas that of Novokuznetsk 550 thousand people. At least in terms of population, these towns belong to the same category. In Tolyatti, the number of the employed is 435 thousand people and, in Novokuznetsk, 328 thousand. In both towns, an almost identical percentage of population can be classed as employed. However, in Tolyatti, fixed assets investment reaches 35098.4 thousand roubles and the average salary 26006.6 roubles, whereas in Novokuznetsk, it is 17719.1 thousand roubles and 28980.2 roubles respectively.

The principal employer in Tolyatti is AvtoVAZ and, in Novokuznetsk [6] EVRAZ. It is worth stressing that, whereas Russia's car market is in the state of stagnation (table 1), the country's metallurgy market is developing

[5; 8].

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

Table 1

A review of Russia's car market

Category Sales, thousand units Sales, billion roubles

January-September Difference January-September Difference

2015 2014 2015 2014

Russian car makes 193 295 - 34% 96 121 - 21%

International makes produced in Russia 519 846 - 39% 600 822 - 27%

New imported cars 238 527 - 55% 349 632 - 45%

Total 950 1667 - 43% 1045 1574 - 34%

Source: [1].

Cluster 3

Cluster 3 brings together such towns as Naberezhnye Chelny and Cherepovets. Both are classed as category 1 in the governmental list. The population size is similar in both towns — 522 thousand people in Naberezhnye Chelny and 316.8 thousand people in Cherepovets. The employment rate in Naberezhnye Chelny is 61.3 % (320 thousand people), and in

Cherepovets 60.4 % (191.1 thousand people). Fixed assets investment is almost identical in these monotowns — 20,679 thousand roubles in Naberezhnye Chelny and 22,098 thousand roubles in Cherepovets. As to the average salary, just as in the other clusters, the values are markedly different — 25,949 roubles in Naberezhnye Cheney against 36,436 roubles in Cherepovets.

It is of interest that both towns are classed as category 1. However, in the case of Cherepovets, 880 million roubles were allocated for the construction of the Cherepovets industrial park [10]. Today, the project includes the construction of a fibrewood panel factory, a gypsum plant, and a pipe plant.

A 2015 governmental decree included Naberezhnye Chelny in the list of monotowns that were granted an advanced development territory (ADT) status [18]. Today it is difficult to assess a town's prospects of acquiring the ADT status, despite tax privileges for business, since the lorry market (Naberezhnye Chelny's principal employer is KamAZ — Russia's largest lorry producer) is very sensitive to fluctuations in the economy. However, international practices of overcoming 'monotown crises' when applied to companies working on ADT suggest that tax privileges contribute to the development of small and medium businesses in a town. Therefore, such initiatives will increase Naberezhnye Chelny's chances of leaving the category of the most depressed monotowns.

Cluster 4

A special case is cluster 4 consisting of only one town — Nizhnekamsk [10], which is classed as category 3. The key parameters analysed in this cluster are as follows:

Population — 235.6 thousand people.

Number of the employed — 146.6 thousand people.

Fixed assets investment — 41113.2 thousand roubles.

Average nominal gross salary — 28892 roubles.

The results are somewhat contradictory. Based on the population size and salary, Nizhnekamsk could be classed as cluster 1 (category 3). However, it is not the case due to fixed assets investment being the largest in the sample.

Cluster 5

It is another cluster consisting of only one town — Norilsk, which is also classed as category 3.

Population — 1,773 thousand people.

Number of the employed — 126.1 thousand people.

Fixed assets investment — 42,881.9 thousand roubles.

Average nominal gross salary — 66,584 roubles.

It is not a coincidence that this cluster comprises only one monotown. When analysing the selected parameters, one can see that the socioeconomic situation in this town is very different from the others. Firstly, the employment rate in Norilsk is much higher than in the other monotowns (above 70%). This is accounted for by the principal employer — Norilsk Nickel —

being a major company and Norilsk the region's second largest city after Krasnoyarsk. Secondly, the values of such parameters as fixed assets investment and salary are much higher than in the other towns, sometimes it is a 1.5—2.5-fold difference.

In other words, the situation in Norilsk is rather stable and favourable. Of course, the reason behind it is the success of the principal employer — the Norilsk Nickel mining and smelting company. In the crisis 2008—2009 years, the company's top priorities were to avoid lay-offs and maintain social stability in the regions of operation [8; 26]. Probably, these priorities helped Norilsk to recover quickly from the crisis. However, local authorities also contributed to overcoming the effects of the 2008—2009 crisis.

In 2010, a modernisation plan for the town of Norilsk was published on the website of the Krasnoyarsk region [6]. The plan was aimed at securing a stable economic development of the town. Local authorities stressed that the viability of the principal employer, its operation, and thus favourable living conditions depended on solving a number of housing and utility problems and the prospects of resettling the non-productive population of Norilsk. This framework gave rise to projects capable of ensuring industrial modernisation and diversification and solving a number of social security issues.

Some measures suggested launching an investment project for mine development, modernisation of housing, water treatment facilities, and urban infrastructure, resettlement within a target resettlement programme, creation of social infrastructure, and opening a landfill site. According to the plan, the projects are to be completed in 2025, thus interim results are not yet available.

Cluster 6

Cluster 6 comprises such towns as Nizhny Tagil and Magnitogorsk, both classed as category 3. The population of the first town is 360.7 thousand people and that of the second 414.9 thousand. The number of the employed is 209.9 thousand people in Nizhny Tagil and 246.8 thousand in Magnitogorsk. Fixed assets investment in Nizhny Tagil is lower than in Magnitogorsk — 12,838 thousand roubles and 17,314 thousand respectively. As to salary, the difference is smaller — 28,643 roubles in Nizhny Tagil and 31,429 roubles in Magnitogorsk. The towns are engaged in the same industry. The principal employer of Magnitogorsk is Magnitogorsk Iron and Steel Works specialising in black metallurgy. Three major companies operating in Nizhny Tagil are EVRAZ (metallurgy), Vysokogorsky mining and processing works (iron ores), and Uralvagonzavod (arms industry).

3. Advanced development territories in monotowns — development initiatives or stimuli for rent-seeking behaviour?

It is important to stress that this sample includes towns that were granted the advanced development territory (ADT) status [2]. As of September 2015, ADT monotowns [17] include Usolye-Sibirskoe (Irkutsk region), Gukovo (Rostov region), Yurga (Kemerovo region), and Naberezhnye Chelny (Re-

public of Tatarstan). The law grants ADT towns a number of privileges — special legal regimes for business and other activities (rent exemptions, tax privileges, and special regimes of public and municipal control) and withdrawal of land for ADT buildings and infrastructure [2].

Let us consider the four 'newcomers' on the monotown list and analyse them from the perspective of homogeneity of socioeconomic situation in the town (table 2).

Table 2

Socioeconomic characteristics of ADT towns

Town Unemployment rate,% Fixed capital investment from the municipal budget, roubles Average salary, thousand roubles Industrial production index, % Proportion of SME revenues

Usolye-Si-birskoe 1.21 23.6 million 20.9 62.7 52.4%

Gukovo 1.2 262.9 million [13] 17.3

Yurga 2.25 [1] 718.6 million [14] 17.9 96.6 [14] No data. There is information that the proportion of tax revenues is approximately 22% [14]

Naberezhnye Chelny 0.81 37,700 million 25.9 96.4 49,000 million roubles[15]

National total 5.2 396,000 million 32.5 101.7 [9]

Source: compiled by the authors based on information from municipalities' official websites.

There are evident differences. Firstly, only one of the four towns — Naberezhnye Chelny — has a population of over 100 thousand people. Of course, this affected the parameter values. However, the other three monotowns show similar performance. A special case is Usolye-Sibirskoe, where fixed assets investment and industrial production index are at the lowest. It is important to take into account not only the obtained values but also the complications relating to data collection.

The discrepancy between the data available on the Rosstat and town administration websites (www. gks. ru suggest that the fixed assets investment in Usolye-Sibirskoe is 23.6 million roubles, whereas, according to the administration website, it is 803.8 million roubles, including 1.1 million rouble investment in construction),

— The lack of necessary data on the websites of state statistics services and town administration (the town of Gukovo).

— The impossibility of comparing data due to initial structural differences characteristic of the selected parameters.

«P -

That is why, a structural analysis of ADT monotowns is just a 'first glance' at their composition, similarities, and differences. In view of the fact that these monotowns specialise in different industries and that they were granted the ADT status not a long time ago, it is difficult to suppose what effect this privileged status will have in the future. In this case, the most appropriate approach would be 'difference in difference', which will make it possible to predict how the 'special status' monotowns will develop as compared to other monotowns. How significant will that difference be?

Another interesting issue is how the other monotowns with a structure similar to ADT towns will react to these privileges. Does it mean that monotowns will work towards acquiring the coveted status? If the socioeconomic situation in a monotown is similar to the national average and this town is granted the ADT status, why is not this status granted to all other towns showing a similar performance? How will it be possible to evaluate the actual situation in a monotown? Are there any guarantees that the situation in an ADT monotown will change for the better? Moreover, the ADT status suggests production diversification, which necessitates retraining the staff and requires additional spending.

These considerations compel one to rephrase the question. Is not it reasonable to discuss this problem parametrically, taking into account that we are dealing with the system of relationships with the information asymmetry. In this case, we should consider both the problem of veracity (and timely submission) of necessary data and that of the 'privileged' position of selected monotowns. It is important to mention that an attempt at modelling was made earlier [20] when discussing an institutional agreement modelling. The reference point is the reasonability of continuing a principal employer's operations accompanied by resettling, changing specialisation due to the transfer of assets from specific to general, or regular monitoring if maintaining specialisation is justified. However, such institutional agreements work only if the problems arising from information asymmetry are solved.

Let us examine the same agreement in terms of information asymmetry. Technically, we are solving the principal-agent problem with the reservation that the principal (the non-informed party) is a federal authority whereas the agent (the informed party) is the management of a monotown's dominant company. However, the system contains another element — regional authorities, which act as an agent for the mentioned principal and a principal for the agent presented by the company's management. In this case, the regional authorities are the key element of the system, since they serve as a mediator6 between the major principal and the agent.

Let us suppose that the management of the dominant company is interested in maximising its profit: 1 — max, where 1 is a certain function of n

6 We understand that there is a possibility that the beneficiaries of a dominant company can address the federal centre directly. However, this variant suggests an interaction between the agent and the regional principal. When it comes to financing, agents will either fulfil their obligations or not, however, the principal does not have this information at the moment.

variables, including assets specificity, selling price, parameters of fixed and variable costs, etc. The management of a dominant company can receive a certain amount of investment f from the federal level for implementing a certain project expected to have a positive effect on a company's profit and, supposedly, the socioeconomic position of the ith monotown under consideration. However, an agent prone to rent-seeking behaviour [22; 24] can doctor information reporting a difficult financial situation to the regional authorities, which, in their turn, will submit an investment application to the federal level. It is important to make the following reservations:

— we suppose that the financial performance of the dominant company has a direct impact on the socioeconomic situation in the monotown (salaries, social benefits, and other parameters);

— the federal principal can monitor the situation in monotowns with a probability of a, therefore it can estimate the company's actual need for additional financing with a probability of (1 - a);

— the regional principal striving to maximise the regional budget and stabilise the socioeconomic situation makes an effort of e1 to monitor the fulfilment of the company's obligations after receiving additional investment [28]. However, the regional principal can also be characterised by rentseeking behaviour [23]. Therefore, it is possible that a part of investment yf, y e (0;1) will be absorbed by the local principal and a part of investment (1 - y)f will be transferred to the dominant company. In this case, the company's management owes obligations to the local principal making an effort of e2 to monitor their fulfilment. Therefore, e2 < e1;

— the regional principal has necessary information and can report the agent failing to meet their obligations to the federal principal, in their turn, the federal principal can impose sanctions s and terminate investment over a period of t + 17.

In view of the above, let us build a probability model. There are following parameters:

PF stands fir the federal principal making investment decisions;

PR stands for the regional principal, aware or unaware of the agent's unreliability. We will consider a case when the PR is aware of the agent's unreliability. Therefore, the former can force the latter to fulfil their obligations with a probability of a2 allocating the full amount of funding or allocate full amount of funding without forcing the latter to fulfil their obligation with a probability of a3. At the same time, PR can act as a rent-seeking actor. Therefore, they can conclude a contract with the agent and force them to fulfil its obligations with a probability of a4 or appropriate part of investment being unaware of the agent's further actions. Here, two relationship systems are possible:

F R f R

PF and Agent — direct interaction, PR and Agent, PF and PR. In the case of direct interaction, the principal monitors the project implementation by

7 It is supposed that a company cannot be 'revitalised' in a year, therefore one should consider T periods, where t e (1,T) with a one year gap. In this case, if a project was approved and investment made in the period t but the agent turned out to be unreliable, in the period t + 1, the investment will equal zero.

«P -

the agent in the period 4 if the latter fails to fulfil their obligations, the agent will learn about it within the period ti+j discontinuing investment in the next period ti+j+1.

However, if we consider the participation of all three actors, the system becomes much more complicated (fig.).

pF cbesnotfinance

p*

Appropriatesf

Probability aj

Trcm^ers par t<ff. .........^

Farces the agent tofulfuil their ï Fuîflîs obligations with a probability of bL

obligations, making cm effort of Al

Probability a2 « Fails to fulfil obligations with a probability qf (I-b j)

Transfers par toff being unaware \Fuf'kobbgaiiom with a probability tfb7

of the agents further actions *

Probability 9

• Fails to fulfil obligations with a probability qf (I-b

Appropr sates part of investment '¡f,

forces the agentfulfil their t. ........^

obligations,making an effort qf e3 \ * Fulfils obligations with a probability of b,

Probability

Appsqprttàspcstqf 'nustneH yf being unaware of the agent's further actions

Fails to fulfil obligations with a probability cf (l-b£

Probability as

^ ; Fulfils obligations with a probability of b4

A •

I Fails to fulfil obligators with a probability tf(l-bj ........^

Fig. Possible scenarios within the model

Let us assume that 2ai = 1, where I = 1,5 и Zbi = 1, где I = 1,4 and, due probability distribution, b3 < b1 and b4 < b2. It is logical to suppose that the most interesting cases are those where the regional principal transfers the full amount of funding to the agent, forcing the latter to fulfil their obligations and when the principal appropriates part of investment, nevertheless, forcing the agent to fulfil their obligations. The first issue we are interested in is the correlation of the efforts made by the mediating principal in these cases. Is it possible that the mediator's actions will encourage the agent to act according to the first scenario? The second issue is the agent's stimuli for fulfilling their obligations. The sanctions s are also taken into account. However, they will hardly have a big enough effect to prevent the actors from rentseeking behaviour. Evidently, the more favourable situation is that with the mediator controlling the agent's actions and the agent's profit exceeding the profit from concluding a contract with the mediator. For the agent, the condition for selecting a strategy (fulfilling obligations) is equivalent to a set of solutions of the inequation a4bf(1 - ) + я< a2b1f + я, i.e. if the amount of in-

r

vestment 'appropriated' by the mediator does not exceed y >

1 _ OA

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

a4b3 J

f.

Then, assuming that the principal's utility is a certain function £ of efforts made to monitor the actions of the agent and some of the significant variables, the area of mutually beneficial cooperation between the principal and agent will be within the set of solutions of the system

r>

! _ a2b1

a4b3

f

£ ^ max

In this case, if the functions are given in a particular form and it is possible to identify the threshold values of efforts made by the principle and the agent's 'remuneration', it is important to understand how these efforts can be evaluated in practice. What can become an actual stimulus for them? This situation necessitates examining informal institutions and cases of overcoming the monotown problem within the considered structure of stakeholders. This, however, requires further study.

Conclusions

Increased activity of both authorities and various initiative groups in the context of the 'monotown problem' requires developing unique methodologies for an empirical analysis of the actual situation in monotowns. One cannot deny the existence of the monotown problem. Of course, it is there, but it is important to understand to what extent it is exaggerated. A clear picture of the problem simplifies the search for relevant solutions.

In this article, we have carried out a quantitative analysis of monotowns based on the existing list of monotowns and their socioeconomic characteristics. The analysis helped obtain the following results.

• Firstly, there is a need for a qualitative approach to selecting parameters taking into account all structural factors reflecting the socioeconomic situation in monotowns. An accurate assessment of the necessary set of parameters simplifies the evaluation of prospects of finding a solution to the monotown problem due to the formation of monotown clusters with similar characteristics; an appropriate approach can be chosen for each cluster;

• Secondly, both availability and accuracy of socioeconomic data can be an issue. When trying to analyse changes in the situation in all monotowns from 2007 to 2014, we had to deal with the absence of data for these years for a large number of monotowns. This is unfortunate, since a panel sample could have become a reference point for developing concepts aimed at solving the monotown problem;

• Thirdly, it is important to consider the ADT status. At this stage, it is impossible to draw any conclusions about the transparency of the principles behind the selection of monotowns entitled to the ADT status. However, one can assume that the possibility of analysing the development of the 'privileged' monotowns in comparison to the rest of them will contribute to identifying key characteristics for acquiring such status and understanding its actual, not perceived, benefits.

References

1. Analiticheskij obzor PwC «Avtomobil'nyj rynok Rossii: rezul'taty za 9 mesja-cev 2015 g.» [PwC Analytical review «Automotive market of Russia: results for the first 9 months of 2015"], 2015, available at: https://www.pwc.ru/ru/automotive/ publications/assets/automotive-nov-2015.pdf (accessed 27.03.2016).

2. Departament truda i zanjatosti naselenija Kemerovskoj oblasti [Department of Labor and Employment of the Kemerovo Region], 2015, available at: http://www. ufz-kemerovo.ru/home/informaciya/statistika.aspx (accessed 27.01.2016).

3. Zakon «O territorijah social'no-jekonomicheskogo razvitija v Rossijskoj Fed-eracii» ot 29 dekabrja 2014 g. № 473-FZ [Federal law "On the territories of socioeconomic development in the Russian Federation" of December 29, 2014 # 473-FZ],

2014.

4. Zubarevich, N. V. 2010, Regiony Rossii: neravenstvo, krizis, modernizacija [Regions of Russia: inequality crisis and modernization], Moscow, 160 p.

5. Indeks cen na lom cvetnyh metallov na rossijskom rynke v dekabre 2015 g. [Price index for scrap non-ferrous metals in Russia in December 2015], 2015, available at: http://www.infogeo.ru/metalls/review/?act=show&rev=1133 (accessed

29.12.2015).

6. Kompleksnyj investicionnyj plan modernizacii monogoroda Novokuzneck [A comprehensive investment plan for the modernization of monotowns Novokuznetsk], 2016, available at: http://monogorod.kemobl.ru/NOVOKUZNETSK/ kipr1.pdf (accessed 01.02.2016).

7. Kompleksnyj investicionnyj plan modernizacii monogoroda Noril'ska [A comprehensive investment plan for the modernization of the Norilsk monotown],

2015, available at: http://econ.krskstate. ru/dat/bin/art_attach/1730_kompleksnij_ investicionnij_plan_modernizacii_monogoroda_norilxska.pdf (accessed 12.12.2015).

8. Obzor rynka chernoj metallurgii za 2015 god [Review of the Steel Market in 2015]. 2015, Deloitte, available at: https://www2.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/ ru/Documents/manufacturing/russian/ru-iron-and-steel-industry-report-ru.pdf (accessed

15.02.2016).

9. Obrashhenie general'nogo direktora [Address by the CEO], 2009, Norilsk Nickel, available at: http://www.nornik.ru/_upload/year2009/obrazhenie_strzhalkovsky. pdf (accessed 17.12.2015).

10. Oficial'nyj sajt gosudarstvennoj statistiki RF [Official website of the state statistics], 2015, available at: http://www.gks.ru (accessed 27.10.2015).

11. Oficial'nyj sajt Nizhnekamskogo municipal'nogo rajona Respubliki Tatar-stan [Official website of the Nizhnekamsk municipal district of the Republic of Ta-tarstan], 2015, available at: http://www.e-nizhnekamsk.ru/infrastruktura/economica/ prom.php (accessed 18.03.2016).

12. Oficial'nyj sajt goroda Cherepovec [Official site of Cherepovets], 2016, available at: http://www. cherinfo. ru/news/78025 (accessed 14.01.2016).

13. Raspoijazhenie №668-p Pravitel'stva RF ot 16 aprelja 2015 g. [Order № 668-p of the RF Government issued on April 16, 2015], 2015, available at: http:// government. ru/media/files/ANTtXeAibvOQUysuIxa7br4h3rjptEYS. pdf (accessed 20.10.2015).

14. Rosstat Rostovskoj oblasti RF [Federal State Statistics Service of the Rostov region of the Russian Federation], 2016, available at: http://rostov.gks.ru/wps/ wcm/connect/rosstat_ts/rostov/resources/56d86200483036ea845ea4ed3bc4492fMHBec-T^HH+B+0CH0BH0H+KanHTa^. html (accessed 19.02.2016).

15. Social'no-jekonomicheskoe razvitie Jurginskogo gorodskogo okruga za 2014 god [Socio-economic development of the city district of Yurga in 2014], 2014, available at: http://www.yurga.org/pagedata/00000190/files/fact_ser2014.pdf, c. 8 (accessed 19.02.2016).

A. Shastitko, A. Fatikhova _

«#»

16. Strategija social'no-jekonomicheskogo razvitija municipal'nogo obra-zovanija goroda Naberezhnye Chelny do 2030 goda [Strategy of socio-economic development of the municipality of Naberezhnye Chelny to 2030], 2015, available at: http://kpfu.ru/portal/docs/F_1500185514/chelny.no.pdf (accessed 19.02.2016).

17. Williamson, O. 1996, Jekonomicheskie instituty kapitalizma. Firmy, rynki, «otnoshencheskaja kontraktacija» [Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Firms, Markets, "Relational Contracting"], St. Petersburg, 702 p.

18. Ulyukayev, A. V. V 4 monogorodah budut sozdany territorii operezhajush-hego razvitija... [4 monotowns to become territories of advanced development...], 2015, available atL http://economy.gov.ru/minec/press/news/20153 00901 (accessed 18.01.2016).

19. Sabirov, R., Idiyatullin, A., Gavrilenko, A. 2015, Chelninskij TOR bla-goslovlen... [Chelny ADT is blessed...], Delovaja jelektronnaja gazeta Biznes Online [Business e-Business Newspaper Online], available at: http://www.business-gazeta. ru/text/142248/ (accessed 19.02.2016).

20. Shastitko, A. E. 2010, Novaja institucional'naja jekonomicheskaja teorija [New Institutional Economics], Moscow, 828 p.

21. Shastitko A., Fatikhova A. 2015, Monotowns: A New Take on the Old Problem, Balt. Reg. no. 1, p. 4—24. DOI: 10.5922/2079-8555-2015-1-1.

22. Boukendour, S. 2007, Preventing post-contractual opportunism by an option to switch from one contract to another, Construction management and economics, T. 25, Vol. 7, p. 723—727.

23. Drugov, M. 2010, Information and delay in an agency model, RAND Journal of Economics, T. 41, Vol. 3, p. 598—615.

24. Foss, N., Stea, D. 2014, Putting a Realistic Theory of Mind into Agency Theory: Implications for Reward Design and Management in Principal Agent Relations, European Management Review, T. 11, Vol. 1, p. 101—116.

25. Kaplan, T., Ruffle, B. 2011, Which way to cooperate, The Economic Journal, T. 122, Vol. 563, p. 1042—1068.

26. Parente, G., Shiklomanov, N., Streletskiy, D. 2012, Living in the New North: Migration to and from Russian Arctic Cities, Focus on Geography, T. 55, Vol. 3, p. 77—89.

27. Ramamohan Rao T. V. S. Estimating the parameters of Principal Agent Models, Journal of Quantitative Economics, T. 13, Vol. 1, p. 27—52.

28. Ronen, J., Yaari, V. 2007, Demand for the truth in principal-agent relationships, Review of accounting studies, T. 12, Vol. 1, p. 125—153.

About the authors

Prof Andrei Shastitko, Head of the Department of Competition and Industrial Policy, Lomonosov Moscow State University; Director, Centre for Competition and Economic Regulation Studies, Russian Presidential Academy of National Economy and Public Administration, Russia.

E-mail: [email protected]

Adelya Fatikhova, Research Fellow, Centre for Competition and Economic Regulation Studies, Russian Presidential Academy of National Economy and Public Administration, Russia.

E-mail: [email protected]

To cite this article:

Shastitko A. E., Fatikhova A. F. Monotowns: A Quantitative Analysis, Baltic region, Vol. 8, no. 2, p. 4—19. doi: 10.5922/2079-8555-2016-2-1.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.