Научная статья на тему 'Domestic price formation of sorghum under export policies in Sudan'

Domestic price formation of sorghum under export policies in Sudan Текст научной статьи по специальности «Экономика и бизнес»

CC BY
147
111
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
Ключевые слова
PRICE FORMATION / EXPORT PAN / INTERVENTION / SUDAN

Аннотация научной статьи по экономике и бизнесу, автор научной работы — Mahmoud Ali Amassaib, Salah Mohamed Elawad, Elrashied Elimam Elkhidir

This paper was prepared to investigate the integration between the domestic and world prices of sorghum and measure the rate of transmission from world price to domestic price of sorghum. The study utilized secondary data covering the period 1970-2007.The data analyzed using dynamic linear regression model. The most important results revealed from the study were that the sorghum domestic price was inelastic in respond to both sorghum production cost and adjusted world prices in short run (0.2668 and 0.39543) and in long run (0.3982 and 0.5901). The effects of adjusted world price implied that devaluation and decrease of tariff rate would lead to increase of sorghum domestic price.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.

Текст научной работы на тему «Domestic price formation of sorghum under export policies in Sudan»

DOMESTIC PRICE FORMATION OF SORGHUM UNDER EXPORT POLICIES IN SUDAN

Mahmoud Ali Amassaib

University of Kordofan, Sudan E-mail: moudamassaib@yahoo.com

Salah Mohamed Elawad, Elrashied Elimam Elkhidir

University of Khartoum, Sudan E-mail: mmmsalah@yahoo.com, rashiedimam@uofk.edu

ABSTRACT

This paper was prepared to investigate the integration between the domestic and world prices of sorghum and measure the rate of transmission from world price to domestic price of sorghum. The study utilized secondary data covering the period 1970-2007.The data analyzed using dynamic linear regression model. The most important results revealed from the study were that the sorghum domestic price was inelastic in respond to both sorghum production cost and adjusted world prices in short run (0.2668 and 0.39543) and in long run (0.3982 and 0.5901). The effects of adjusted world price implied that devaluation and decrease of tariff rate would lead to increase of sorghum domestic price.

KEY WORDS

Price formation, Export pan, Intervention, Sudan.

Intervention in prices of sorghum in Sudan has involved many policy instruments, including export quotas and price support. Export quotas have been a key feature of controlled prices of sorghum for previous decades. They had been implemented as means of stabilizing and increasing of sorghum producers' prices and hence raising producers' income. Price support programs displayed as government purchase of sorghum buffer stock through the Strategic Commodity Reserve Authority (SCRA) with the main functions of market stabilization, mainly for staple cereals, through imports and local purchases, and the free and/or subsidized distribution of food to vulnerable groups, and through Agricultural Bank of Sudan. Others tools of macroeconomic policies that affected sorghum prices such as devaluation of local currency, taxes reform ... etc were used. Marketing and stock policies in general continued within the same line of market liberalization adopted previously. Similarly, with the view that privatization improves market efficiency, Sudan granted the private sector a bigger role in the marketing and trading of sorghum.

The sorghum prices respond to macroeconomic shocks and to sector-specific shocks. Under such circumstance producers of sorghum in mechanized rainfed subsector would be in conditions of risk and uncertainty about price stability and volatility. Price instability remain a major concern for decision makers because the importance of sorghum in Sudan's food security as a main staple food crop. For a few decades, dramatic changes in sorghum prices in domestic markets with increase in costs of production and deterioration in sorghum yield and in rain fall had put producers of sorghum in critical situation because of price instability. Moreover, sorghum producers have not always been entirely protected from the consequences of price instability and had limited ability to deal it.

In many seasons the government interferes to determine floor prices for the benefit of producers and to stabilize price fluctuations prices, but there were hardly sorghum administered prices. The behaviour of sorghum price showed instability through different periods, the coefficient of variations of different markets and for average levels was high. The volatility of nominal prices for total period (1970-2006) was more than 170%, respectively in different markets (Table 1).

The fluctuations were most likely influenced by the controls on exports (and imports). Converse relationship between domestic price and export comes from the purpose of the export policies. The decision of export is made for controlling the level of domestic price. If the domestic price is high then the policy makers put constrains on sorghum export. When domestic price is low the policy makers use export bans to increase price of sorghum.

Table 1 - The Coefficient of Variation of nominal sorghum prices 1970-2006 in selected markets

^^^ Items Period Gadarif Kosti Madni Obeid Average

1970-1978 41.2 39.1 39.0 26.6 31.4

1978-1985 149.7 143.8 146.8 126.7 140.8

1985-1992 141.6 138.7 127.4 136.5 135.4

1992-2002 80.1 82.4 78.8 87.6 81.5

2002-2006 39.6 36.3 39.2 31.1 35.2

1970-2006 175.2 174.3 177.3 172.2 173.5

Source: Ministry of Agriculture & Forests (2008) & Central Bureau of Statistics (2008) http://www.cbs.gov.sd

The export restrictions are often decided after planting, leading to a classical cobweb cycle effect, with production increasing as prices decline and vice versa. Different literature highlighted on transmission of global prices into domestic prices (Headey 2011 and Skoufias et al., 2011). The global prices do put upward pressure on domestic prices when they are rising, even though downward movements are less rapidly or effectively transmitted and often do not have any such impact. As Wood et al. (2010) said some researcher commented that lower food prices to be advantageous to the poor (Aksoy and Isik-Dikmelik, 2008) and higher food prices to be generally harmful to consumers in developing countries (Ivanic and Martin, 2008; DeHoyos and Medvedev, 2009).

The objective of this paper is to investigate the integration between the domestic and world prices of sorghum and measure the rate of transmission from world price to domestic price of sorghum.

MATERIALS AND METHODS OF RESEARCH

Culff (2003) gave model for price formation, which is adopted by Meyer (2007). The model implies the following equation:

Ptd = a + pPtw. rt .(1- d) + £t

where: Ptd and Ptw domestic and world prices at time t; P imperfect transmission between domestic and world prices; rt exchange rate; d represent tariff; and a and et capture the divergence of world and domestic prices that does not depend on price level. Depending on equation above the price transmission elasticity of export can be calculated as follows:

n = (d Ptd -d Ptw)*(Ptw - Ptd) = P (1+ d)*( [Ptw .r] - Ptd)

It is interesting to note that a long time series gives no guarantee of precise estimates because the longer data are susceptible to incorporate different policy regimes (Culff, 2003). So, the domestic price model for sorghum is set as follow:

Pdt = P0 + P1Pdt-1 +P2Pwadj + P3PCt +et Pwadj = Ptw. rt .(1- d) Two models were used to estimate the above functions which are:

1. The model which known as dynamic linear regression (DLR). The simplest Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) (1, 1) model is:

yt =a0+a1yt-1 +P0 Xt+P1Xt-1+ £t

where: it is assume that £t ~ iid (0, o2) and la1 <1 (Elawad, 2001).

2. The model which known as Error Correction model (ECM) that implied ARDL (1, 1). The model can be written as:

AY, = a0 - a1 (YM - PZt-1) + P0 AZt + Dt + et

where: Z is a vector of regressors and pi reflect the equilibrium effect of the individual Z regressors on Y. D is a dummy variable while at is an estimated coefficient in the regression and A is the difference operator (Mose, 2007; Keele and De Boef, 2004).

Performance of the models could be measured by the validity of the estimation, ability of reproduce of the actual data in a dynamic simulation and stability. The estimating model in this study has been evaluated and validated on the basis of root mean square percentage error (RMSPE), and Theil's inequality coefficient (U). Theil's inequality coefficient is defined as follow (see K. and Roy (2014)):

U= [1/n! (Pt-At)2 / (1/n!A2+1/n!P2)]1/2

where: Pt and At represent predicted and actual values at the same time t respectively, while n is the number of observations. Theil's coefficient lies in the interval between zero and one. In case of perfect prediction, Theil's coefficient takes the value zero. The source of prediction errors could also be identified by taking into account the numerator of Theil's inequality coefficient, Um, Us and Uc .

Um = (P-A) 2 / [1/n! (Pt-At)2 ] Us = (sd P-sd A) 2 / [1/n! (Pt-At)2 ] Uc = 2(1-r)sd P*sd A/ [1/n! (Pt-At)2 ]

where: Um = the bias proportion it is an indication of systematic error, with a value close to zero is desirable

Us = the variance proportion which measure the equality between the standard deviation of predicted (sd P) and actual (sdA) values. The value close to zero is desirable. Uc = the covariance proportion measure the unsystematic error, with a value close to one is desirable.

P = the mean of predicted value. A = the mean of actual value

r = the correlation coefficient between predicted and actual values. Further, the models would be validated by RMSPE.

RMSPE =[1/n! {(Pt-At)/ At} 2] * *100

RESULTS OF STUDY

According to Table (2), statistically all regressors have expected signs. The coefficient of the determination, R2 (0.923), together with F-ratio (132.77) indicate the goodness of fit of the equation. The diagnostic tests explain no error serial correlation (F-ratio =2.461) and no heteroscedasticity (F-ratio =0.857) but the normality of the residual is not satisfied (Jarque-Bera coefficient = 8.627, (0.013)).

The performance of domestic price model estimated on the basis of RMSPE and the Theil's coefficients in Table (2) with Figure (1) show the ability of the model to track the direction of the actual values of domestic price and explain the performance of the long domestic price response. Moreover, cointegration test in Figure (2) emphasized this long relationship.

Table (2): Short and long run coefficients of domestic price model for sorghum production in MRS

Coefficient Variable Definition Estimate short run Estimate long run

ßo C Intercept 3.71445 5.5439

ßi Pdt-i Lagged domestic price 0.3297*** (0.03316)

ß2 PWadj Adjusted world price 0.26680*** (0.04376) 0.3982

ß3 PCt Sorghum production cost 0.39543*** (0.033675) 0.5901

Notes: all variables are in Ln form

R-Squared =0.923Adj R-Squared = 0.921F-Ratio = 132.77(0.000000) Asterisk *** significant at 1 percent level Asterisk ** significant at 5 percent level Asterisk * significant at 10 percent level Figures between parentheses are standard error value Diagnostic test:

Error serial correlation F statistics =2.461(0.125) Heteroscedasticity F statistics =0.857(0.360) Error Probability, Jarque-Bera coefficient =8.627 (0.013) Theil's inequality coefficient (U) =0.030 Theil's inequality coefficient (Um) =0.003 Theil's inequality coefficient (Us) =0.020 Theil's inequality coefficient (U°) =1.00 The root mean square percentage error =0.1096

16

12

1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

ACTUAL

PREDICTED

RESIDUAL

Figure 1 - Actual and predicted domestic price and the residuals of the model for

sorghum production in MRS

in n o

+j

J5 0

O o o

+J

<

1.0

0.5

0.0

-0.5

-1.0

0.0

Aicoorrelácns of residual (0,0,12,0,0)

111

8.8

17.5 Time

ro Q_

-i—i—i—i—i—i—i

26.3 35.0

1.0

0.5

o o

o 0.0

D

<

-0.5

-1.0

0.0

FPartial Autocorrélations of residua (0,0,12,0,0)

I ! ' I ■ ■ I I ' ' I I ' I I ' ' ■ I ■ I I ' I ■ I

—I—I—I— 8.8

17.5 Time

-i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i

26.3 35.0

Figure 2 - Cointegration test of domestic price model for sorghum production in MRS (significant if |correlation|> 0.328798)

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

Table (2) shows that all variables (i.e. lagged domestic price, adjusted world price and sorghum production cost) selected in the model have strong effect on the dependent variable (domestic farmer price). Moreover, they have elasticities less than one in short and in long

terms. Adjusted world price calculated as Culff (2003) model. So, exchange rate and export tariff are included in the model of domestic price.

Error Correction Model in Table (3) has found to be statistically significance (at 5 percent level), indicating the existence of the long term causal relationship between the model's variables. The negative sign of ERM coefficient implies slow down effect of error term, and its magnitude indicates small speed of adjustment of the dependent variable to error term. Also, the results proved the significance of sorghum production cost at 1 percent level as adjusting factor for short term disequilibrium of the dependent variable.

Table (3): Error correction coefficients of domestic price model for sorghum production in MRS

Coefficient Variable Definition Estimate

Bo C Intercept -0.1493

Bi PWadj Adjusted world price -0.1292 (0.1348)

B2 PCt Sorghum production cost 0.5911*** (0.1245)

B3 ECM-i Error correction model -0.1824** (0.08713)

Notes: all variables are in differences form

R-Squared =0.299Adj R-Squared = 0.281F-Ratio = 4.545(0.009)

Asterisk *** significant at 1 percent level

Asterisk ** significant at 5 percent level

Asterisk * significant at 10 percent level

Figures between parentheses are standard error value

ECM=Pdt-0.3982*Pwadj -0.5901*PCt -5.5439

DISCUSSION

Sudan policy makers apply export pan to control sorghum domestic price levels under assumption of trade theories. That means the effects of world prices transmitted to sorghum domestic prices but the result of the study revealed that the world price have no such impact on domestic price i.e. the effect was inelastic. So, attaining stabilities in sorghum domestic levels and hence good performances in sorghum production under this trade policy would be limited. The effects of others tow policy instruments applied in Sudan (exchange rate and tariff) which captured by coefficient of adjusted world price. Elawad (2001) cited that real exchange rate devaluation have had positive effect on agricultural supply, although the first round effects result in cost-push inflation. Policy makers deal with devaluation as incentive policy. But, according to results of this study the impact of devaluation policies in domestic prices was limited because of inelastic coefficient of world prices. Currency devaluation in Sudan has been implemented without given due to attention to incorporating such devaluation as a part and parcel of integrated policy package and frequent devaluation has had to a great extent minimized the impact of devaluation as a means of providing incentives to producers (Elawad, 2001). Government interventions via tariff rate make a distortion in sorghum domestic price. This distortion appears in the instability of domestic price relative to which has prevailed under no intervention (Valdes, 1993). As it was shown in the result of the study, the coefficient of adjusted world price explained that increasing tariff rate will decrease sorghum domestic price which mean non-incentive policy for sorghum production.

CONCLUSION

Although domestic and world prices of sorghum are positively integrated, yet the response was inelastic with rate of transmission less than one (close to zero) in short and in long terms. Hence, domestic trade policies of controlling domestic price through export ban would have poor effects on price efficiency and sorghum production performance in both short and long terms. Moreover, the effects of adjusted world price via devaluation and decrease of tariff rate would result in increasing sorghum domestic price in the long run.

REFERENCES

1. Headey, D. (2011). Was the global food crisis really a crisis? Simulations versus self-reporting", IFPRI Working Paper No 1087. http://www.ifpri.org/publication/was-global-food-crisis-reaiiy-crisis).

2. Skoufias E, Tiwari E & Zaman H, 2011. Can we rely on cash transfers to protect dietary diversity during food crises? Estimates from Indonesia. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 5548, World Bank, Washington DC.

3. Wood, B; Nelson C. and and Nogueira, L. (2010). Measuring the Welfare Impact of Food Price Increases on Mexican Households (8/12/10 version for revision), corresponding author: ACE Department, 1301 W. Gregory Dr., Urbana, IL 61801, USA email: chnelson@illinois.edu, telephone: 1-217-333-1822.

4. [Aksoy, A. and Isik-Dikmelik A. (2008). Are low food prices pro-poor? Technical report, World Bank Development Research Group, Working Paper 4642.

5. Ivanic, M. and Martin W. (2008). Implications of higher global food prices for poverty in lowincome countries. Agricultural Economics, 39(s):405-416.

6. DeHoyos, R. and Medvedev D. (2009). Poverty effects of higher food prices: A global perspective.Technical report, World Bank policy research working paper.

7. Culff, M. (2003). A Review of spatial price transmission in major world commodity models. Paper provide to Aglink Users Group, OECD.

8. Meyer, F. H. (2007). Model closure and price formation under switching grain market regimes in South Africa. A Thesis submitted to Ph.D. Department of Agricultural Economics, Extension, and Rural Development. Faculty of Natural and agricultural Science. University of Pretoria.

9. Elawad, S. M. (2001). Supply response of Sudan's cotton industry: Implications of government intervention. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis, University of Purtra, Malaysia.

10. Mose, Lawrence O. (2007).Who gains, who loses? The impact of market liberalisation on rural households in Northwestern Kenya. PhD Thesis, Wageningen University. ISBN 908504-634-3.

11. Keele, L. and De Boef, S. (2004). Not just for cointegration: Error correction models with stationary data. <http://www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/Politics/ papers /2005/Keele%20DeBoef% 20ECM%2004 213.pdf>. Downloaded on 19.06.2006.

12. K, Nithin and Roy, Rathin (2014). Finance Commission of India's Assessments: A Political Economy Contention between Expectations and Outcomes. National Institute of Public Finance and Policy New Delhi http://www.nipfp.org.in. Working Paper No. 2014141.

13. Valdes, A. (1993). The Macroeconomic environment necessary for agricultural trade and policy reform. Food Policy: 272-282.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.