Научная статья на тему 'Definition of the concepts of conventional and non-conventional projects'

Definition of the concepts of conventional and non-conventional projects Текст научной статьи по специальности «Экономика и бизнес»

CC BY-NC-ND
694
109
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
Журнал
Бизнес-информатика
ВАК
RSCI
Область наук
Ключевые слова
типичный инвестиционный проект / нетипичный инвестиционный проект / внутренняя норма доходности / чистый дисконтированный доход / обобщенный чистый дисконтированный доход / conventional investment project / non-conventional investment project / internal rate of return / net present value / generalized net present value

Аннотация научной статьи по экономике и бизнесу, автор научной работы — Anastasia N. Blaset Kastro, Nikolay Yu. Kulakov

Понятие «нетипичный», «нестандартный» проект или «проект с нетипичными денежными потоками» введено в экономическую литературу после того, как было показано, что для некоторых проектов внутренняя нома доходности (internal rate of return, IRR) может иметь несколько значений или не существовать вовсе. Проект считается «типичным», если его денежный поток только один раз меняет знак, независимо от направления: с минуса на плюс или наоборот. Типичный проект имеет единственное значение IRR. Однако не все проекты с многократным изменением знака денежного потока являются «нетипичными», т.е. имеют проблемы с определением IRR. Поэтому теория рекомендует для определения типа проекта исследовать зависимость функции чистого дисконтированного дохода (net present value, NPV) от ставки дисконтирования на монотонность с целью выявления множественности или отсутствия IRR. С другой стороны, монотонность NPV и единс венное значение IRR не гарантируют того, что проект типичный. Более того, было показано, что доходность нетипичного проекта в рамках подхода NPV не может быть определена, а, следовательно, и понятие доходности не может быть сформулировано. Недавно был предложен метод обобщенной чистой приведенной стоимости (generalized net present value, GNPV), на основе которого может быть рассчитана доходность «нетипичного» проекта. В данной статье сформулировано понятие доходности для инвестиционного проекта любого типа и доказана ее тождественность обобщенной внутренней норме доходности (generalized internal rate of return, GIRR), вытекающей из метода GNPV. Дается определение и формулируются необходимое и достаточное условия типичного и нетипичного проекта.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.

Определения типичного и нетипичного проектов

The term “non-conventional” project or “project with non-conventional cash fl ows” was introduced into economic literature after the internal rate of return (IRR) was shown to have multiple values or not exist at all in some projects. A project is considered to be conventional if it has only one change in the cash fl ow sign, no matter whether minus to plus or vice versa. A conventional project has a unique IRR. However, not all projects with a multiple sign change in cash fl ow are non-conventional, i.e. have problems with IRR determination. To ascertain the project type, the generally accepted approach recommends investigating monotony of the net present value (NPV) depending on the discount rate in order to fi nd out how many IRRs the project has. On the other hand, neither the monotony of the NPV function nor a unique IRR guarantee that the project is conventional. The IRR is known to be a rate of return for a conventional investment project rather than a non-conventional project. Moreover, it was shown that the rate of return of a non-conventional project cannot be determined within the framework of the NPV method, and therefore the concept of profi tability cannot be formulated. The recently proposed generalized net present value (GNPV) method allows us to determine the rate of return of a non-conventional project. This paper presents a method to determine the rate of return for an investment project of any type and proves that in the case of a conventional project the rate of return is the IRR, while in the case of a non-conventional project it is the generalized internal rate of return (GIRR). The necessary and suffi cient conditions of conventional and non-conventional projects have been formulated.

Текст научной работы на тему «Definition of the concepts of conventional and non-conventional projects»

Definition of the concepts of conventional and non-conventional projects

Anastasia N. Blaset Kastro

Consultant, Compulink Group

Address: 45, Michurinskiy Prospect, Moscow, 119607, Russian Federation E-mail: [email protected]

Nikolay Yu. Kulakov

Chief Financial Officer, Venta Investment & Finance Company Address: 3^, Leningradskiy Prospect, Moscow, 125284, Russian Federation E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

The term "non-conventional" project or "project with non-conventional cash flows" was introduced into economic literature after the internal rate of return (IRR) was shown to have multiple values or not exist at all in some projects. A project is considered to be conventional if it has only one change in the cash flow sign, no matter whether minus to plus or vice versa. A conventional project has a unique IRR. However, not all projects with a multiple sign change in cash flow are non-conventional, i.e. have problems with IRR determination. To ascertain the project type, the generally accepted approach recommends investigating monotony of the net present value (NPV) depending on the discount rate in order to find out how many IRRs the project has. On the other hand, neither the monotony of the NPV function nor a unique IRR guarantee that the project is conventional. The IRR is known to be a rate of return for a conventional investment project rather than a non-conventional project. Moreover, it was shown that the rate of return of a non-conventional project cannot be determined within the framework of the NPV method, and therefore the concept of profitability cannot be formulated. The recently proposed generalized net present value (GNPV) method allows us to determine the rate of return of a non-conventional project.

This paper presents a method to determine the rate of return for an investment project of any type and proves that in the case of a conventional project the rate of return is the IRR, while in the case of a non-conventional project it is the generalized internal rate of return (GIRR). The necessary and sufficient conditions of conventional and non-conventional projects have been formulated.

Key words: conventional investment project, non-conventional investment project, internal rate of return, net present value, generalized net present value.

Citation: Blaset Kastro A.N., Kulakov N.Yu. (2016) Definition of the concepts of conventional and non-conventional projects. Business Informatics, no. 2 (36), pp. 16—23. DOI: 10.17323/1998-0663.2016.2.16.23.

Introduction

The term "non-conventional" / "non-normal" project or "project with non-conventional cash flows" was introduced in economic literature after it had been discovered that the internal rate of return (IRR) could not be used to assess project effectiveness (i.e. the IRR is not the rate of return of a project in the classic sense). A project is considered to be conventional

if its cash flows have only one change in sign, no matter whether minus to plus or plus to minus [1, 2]. According to this definition, all projects with cash flows having multiple changes in sign are automatically referred to as non-conventional projects. However, this cannot be justified from the methodological point of view: multiple changes in sign are a property (necessary condition) of non-conventional projects, but not a definition (attribute) allowing us to clearly differentiate between

conventional and non-conventional projects. In order to determine the project type, the generally accepted approach recommends considering the property of the function NPV(r): its monotony and existence of a multiple-valued IRR or absence of an IRR. However, neither monotony of the function NPV(r) nor the unique real-valued IRR is an attribute of a conventional project. This proposition is refuted by Gronchi [3] when describing a project with the following cash flows: (—100, 270, —270, 170). This project has a monotonically decreasing function NPV(r), a unique real value IRR = 70%, but is not a conventional project1.

A sufficient condition is considered to be an attribute in logic and mathematics. Among the researchers who formulated a sufficient condition of a conventional project are de Faro & Soares [4], Soper [5], Gronchi [3], Cannaday et al. [6], Bussey & Eschenbach [7], Tei-chroew et al. [8], Bernhard [9], Hajdasinski [10], Hazen [11], Beaves [12], Lohmann [13], Kulakov & Kulakova [14]. The majority of economists consider the same sign of the present (or future) value of a project at the rate equal to the IRR to be a sufficient condition of a conventional project [9—13]. Some economists believe that the project type depends on the discount rate. For example, Teichroew et al. [8] and Hazen [11] determine project region changes of the discount rate for a nonsimple project, where the projects are termed as a pure investment, mixed and pure financial regions. At the same time, Magni supposes that by choosing a discount rate in each period at discretion one can convert a conventional project into a non-conventional one [15]. In our opinion, this proposition is erroneous: the project type should not depend on the discount rate. Besides, the existence of different versions is based on the fact that there is no mathematical definition of conventional and non-conventional projects. To-date no criterion or necessary and sufficient condition identifying a project type has been formulated. This paper offers a solution to the problem in question.

It has long been recognized that non-conventional projects have problems with determination of the IRR as the rate of return of a project. However, it is the imperfections of the NPV method that lie at the root of the problems with the IRR [14, 16]. The rate of return of a non-conventional project cannot be determined within the framework of the NPV method. Generalization of the NPV to the GNPVby using different rates when at-

tracting and reinvesting funds instead of a single rate allows us to resolve the problems with the NPV wrongly attributed to the IRR. In the next section, we formulate the mathematical formulae determining the rate of return for any project type, both conventional and non-conventional, and we prove that in the case of a conventional project the rate of return is the IRR, and in the case of a non-conventional project it is the GIRR [17]. After that, we define and formulate the necessary and sufficient condition for conventional and non-conventional projects. In the fifth section, we present examples of two types of projects with comments followed by conclusions.

1. Determination of the rate of return of an investment project

Since the IRR is the rate of return of a conventional project, it is necessary to start with the definition of the rate of return of an investment project. Bierman and Smidt have suggested the following definition: "The internal rate of return of a conventional investment represents the highest rate of interest an investor could afford to pay on debt without losing money if all funds to finance the investment were borrowed and the loan (principal and accrued interest) was repaid by application of the cash proceeds from the investment as they were earned" [18]. Based on this definition, the interest rate on a loan can be determined as follows: "The loan interest rate (rate of cost) represents the minimum rate of return of an external project in which the borrowed funds can be invested to generate sufficient income to repay the loan with the accrued interest".

In order to avoid excessive repetitions, we will consider only investment projects. First, let us take a simple project consisting of only two cash flows: negative CF0 and positive CF1. As the initial cash flow is negative (CF0 < 0), additional capital has to be raised to finance the project. Suppose a loan S0 = — CF0 with an interest rate r per period is granted. After a period, the loan with the accrued interest will be equal to S1 = S0 (1+ r). The rate r* at which the total amount of debt will be equal to the income CFX is the rate of return of the investment project S1 (r *) = CFl, the rate r* being the highest interest rate an investor can afford without a loss. We next prove the proposition.

Proof: The function St(r) monotonically increases as the discount rate increases because

1 The cash flow considered by Gronchi is a special case project: -A, A (2+r), —A (2+r), A (1+r), where A is the initial investment, and r = IRR. This project is non-conventional, because the present values changes sign: PV3 = A (1+r) > 0, PV2 = -A (2+r) + A = = -A (1+r) < 0, PV1 = A (2+r) - A = A (1+r) > 0, PV0 = -A + A = 0.

dSl dr

= S0=-CF0> 0.

Indeed, for 5 >0 and r = r*+8 we have: Sl(r) — CFi = = S0 (1+r) - CF, = 50 (1+*) + 50 d — CF1 = 5^0 S > 0. QED. The debt will not be repaid.

Now let us consider an investment project containing more than two cash flows. Let CF be the project's cash flows in period i, where i = 0, 1, ... , N. Suppose that the flows are formed at the beginning of every period. If the project balance is negative in some period, a loan will be borrowed to finance the project, and the resulting debt (loan with accrued interest) is repaid at the beginning of the next period. Payments on the current debt are made from cash inflow or a new loan covering the previous debt and outflow of this period. Thus, the debt balance S. in period i is determined as follows:

_ _ \~CF<-So - -CF0,SM

í+i + 5, (1 + r) if S, > 0, + 51 if S, < 0, (1)

i = 0, ... , N - 1, where r — an interest rate.

Technically, the debt balance of the project corresponds to the investment stream [11], the negative un-recovered investment balance stream [7], the project balance [8], the capital invested [13]. It should be noted that no interest is charged on the negative debt balance. The rate r* at which the debt will be repaid at the end of the project SN{r*) = 0 is the rate of return of the project. Let us prove that r* is the highest and unique rate. We will calculate a derivative of the debt balance for every period from the beginning to the end of the project. In period 1 we have:

dSl

dr

■ = S„=- CFn > 0.

In period i:

Let the debt balance be positive in every period from 0 to i-1, and negative in period i.

As St=-CFt+ 5,._! (1 + r) < 0 then SM = - CFM + S.

Let us calculate a derivative of the debt balance in period i+l:

^ = fr(-CFM+Si) = ^(-CF+Sj_](1 + /•)) = > 0.

By calculating the debt balance derivative for subsequent periods until the end of the project, we will obtain

^T = Jr(- CFn +SN.^ + r)) =5JV_1>0.

Therefore, the debt balance SN (r). is a monotonically increasing function of an interest rate r; so if the equation SN (r) = 0 has a solution, then the solution is unique. For a solution to exist, the sum of all cash flows has to be positive, in which case the debt balance at a zero interest rate will be negative.

SN(0) = -ftCFl<0

1=0

(Corollary of the Intermediate Value Theorem).

Thus, the definition of the rate of return of an investment project is as follows: Let CF. where i = 0, 1, ... , N be the project's cash flows. If there exists a rate r* such that — 1 < r* < o° and the following conditions hold:

S0 ~-CF0,

S.j.

\~CFi+ ~[-CFi+

+5, (1 + /**) ifS, > 0,

+5,

ifS,< 0,

i = 0, ..., N - 1

(2.1) (2.2)

SN(r*) = 0 (2.3)

then rate r* is the rate of return of the investment project.

The given definition is suitable for both conventional and non-conventional projects. We can now go on to define a conventional project.

The definition of a conventional project: If the IRR is the rate of return of an investment project, then the project is conventional. The converse is also true: if the project is conventional, the IRR is its rate of return.

Although the above definition is not new, it enables us to formulate a necessary and sufficient condition for the conventional project, namely: for the IRR to be the rate of return of an investment project, it is necessary and sufficient that all project present values discounted by the IRR should be positive in every period except the initial one.

2. Necessary and sufficient conditions signifying that a given project is conventional (the IRR is its rate of return) 2.1. Sufficient condition

Let CF. be project's cash flows, where CF0 < 0 and ^LCF. > 0, i = 0, 1, ... , N. If for V i there exists —1 < r < 00 and the following conditions hold:

PVM > 0, where PV,, = CF.,, PV, =

PV

' 1+

1 + r

■ + CE,

(3.1)

(3.2)

NPV(r) = PVa(r) = 0. (3.3)

Then the discount rate r is the rate of return of the project and the project is conventional.

Proof: We will calculate a derivative of the present value with respect to the discount rate. The derivative of the present value at time i with respect to rate r is equal to:

■■N.

dPVN _dCFN = 0, i

dr dr

dPVt (pvm \ + CFt - ( pvm

dr dr U + r y 1 + r

i=N-\, ... , 0.

- + -

dPV.^

dr )\ + r

dPV.

Thus, if for Vi PVi+! > 0, then the derivative-L < 0,

dr

consequently the function PV. (r) monotonically decreases as the rate r increases. Continuing the

dNPV(r)

calculation until time i = 0, we get-< 0. Thus,

dr

the NPV(r) monotonically decreases as the discount rate increases. Therefore, the equation NPV (IRR) = 0 can have a single real root.

Note that r* from the equation SN(r*) = 0 (2.3) coincides with (is the same as) the IRR. It is evident that SN(r*) = -NPV(r*)(l + r*)N. So, if NPV0 (r*) = 0, then SN (r*) = 0. Therefore, if conditions (3) are met, the IRR is the project's rate of return.

2.2. Necessary condition

Let CF.be the project's cash flows, where i = 0, 1, ..., N and the project's IRR be its rate of return. Then we have

N s-<p

NPV(r*) = y-'— = 0 and

SN(r*) = -NPV(r*)(i+r*)N = 0 . Let us prove that for

Vi < N \ S,(r*)> 0. Proof: Let 3k * N for which Sk (r*) < 0 then:

-CFk+l+Sk^SN

= -^CF^ + r*)" ' => SN(r*) = m + r*)N-1).

(4)

But then the equation SN(r*) =-NPV(r*)(\ + r*)N is wrong. Therefore, every S. should be positive.

The proof provided of a necessary condition perhaps is not strict enough to define a non-conventional project. Another proof can be found in [19].

The definition of a non-conventional project: Replacing "is" with "is not" might seem logical: If the IRR is not the rate of return of an investment project, then the project is non-conventional. However, the IRR may not exist either at all or in a given interval of the discount rate range. This case will be considered in the next sec-

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

tion of the paper. Let us now consider a case when the IRR does exist.

Necessary and sufficient conditions signifying that a given project is non-conventional:

Let us have a project with cash flows CF., where i = 0, ..., N, N> 3 and the following conditions hold:

If for 0 < r < «> 3 i, j e N, ... , 1; (i± j) so that: PV. > 0 and PV. < 0 , where

PVN=CFN, PV¡

PV^

-+CF„ PV0(r) = 0 (5)

(1 + r)

Then the project is non-conventional.

The NPV(r) is a function of the Nth degree of the discount rate r. However, the debt balance function SJ^r) will have the maximum power of r which is less than N according to (4). Therefore, the rate r defined by conditions (5) is not the rate of return.

The converse is also true: If r* ^ IRR then 3 PV. < 0.

l

Proof: According to conditions NPV (IRR) = 0, NPV(IRR) ■ (1+IRR)N = 0, since IRR ï -1. Let us assume that for Vi PV. (IRR) > 0. Then

CF

0 = NPV(IRR) ■ (1 + IRRf= £ -

S (1 + /**)

N

= YJCFl{\ + IRR)Ni = -SN (IRR) = 0.

7(1 + IRRy=

(6)

But r* from (2) is not equal to the IRR, which means that SN (IRR) ^0; as a result, we have got a contradiction of 3 k for which PVk (IRR) < 0.

Unfortunately, it is impossible to use this definition in the case when the non-conventional project has no the IRR. Nevertheless, the rate of return of the non-conventional project does exist and can be defined in terms of the GNPV method.

Generalizing the NPV (the GNPV method)

Several researchers point out the advantages [16] and even justify [17] the application the NPV method to non-conventional projects. Kulakov and Kulakova [14] have recently proposed the GNPV method, which generalizes the NPVmethod by using two discount rates (finance and reinvestment).

The GNPV function is determined by consistently discounting cash flows from the end to the beginning of the project. If the present value of the project in a certain period is positive, we use the internal discount rate, otherwise — the external one. The internal rate determines

the cost of funding an investment, and the external rate determines the return on the investment. The GNPV function is determined as follows [14]:

PVM = CF.,

PV^

PV,=

(1 + r) otherwise

+ CFi,ifPVM> 0,

PV^

(1+ P) GNPV(r,p) = PV0

+ CFn where i = N-1, ... ,0;

(6.1)

(6.2)

(6.3)

where CF. is the project's cash flow in period i, (i = N, ... , 0); PV. is the project's present value in period i; r and p are the internal and the external discount rate, respectively.

To find the roots of the GNPV function it is necessary to solve the equation:

GNPV(r,p) = 0

(7)

The solution of this equation can be sought in the form of r = r(p) or p = p(r) depending on the purpose of non-conventional project evaluation. The GIRR is a rate of return and represents the maximum interest rate on the loan borrowed to finance the project, with the resulting income of the current project used to repay the principal amount and the accrued interest. The GIRR (p) is the function of the reinvestment rate p. The GERR (r) is a rate of cost and represents the minimum rate of return of an external project in which the borrowed funds can be invested to generate sufficient income to repay the loan with the accrued interest.

The systems of the equations (2) are equivalent to (6-7) if ratep is equal to 0.

3. Discussion

Let us consider several projects using the above approach.

3.1. A project (cash flows change sign more than once)

Let us consider a project with cash flows having multiple changes in sign (Table 1).

Table 1.

A conventional project

Period 0 1 2 3

Cash flows -100.0 111.7 -90.0 120.0

NPV at r = 20% 0.0 120.0 10.0 120.0

GNPV(r, 0) 0.0 120.0 10.0 120.0

Although the cash flows change sign more than once, the project's IRR is unique and equal to 20%. As all project present values are positive in every period except the initial one, the project is conventional.

The highest loan interest rate r* at which the project income covers the loan and accrued interests without loss is 20% per year (Table 2). Therefore r* is the rate of return of the project. The IRR is equal to r*, so the project is conventional.

Table 2.

Cash flow statement (the loan interest rate is 20%)

Period 0 1 2 3

Operating 0 91.7 -1.7 100.0

Interest payments 0 -20.0 -1.7 -20.0

Cash received from project 0 111.7 0 120.0

Investing -100 0 -90.0

Cash paid to project -100 0 -90.0

Financing 100 -91.7 91.7

Borrowing loan 100 0 91.7

Loan repayment 0 -91.7 0 -100.0

Debt balance 100 8.3 100.0 0.0

3.2. Two similar projects of different type

Let us consider two similar projects (Table 3, Table 4), which have the same changes in sign and cash flows in every period except the last one.

Ta ble 3.

A conventional project

Period 0 1 2 3

Cash flows -100.0 120.0 -100.0 120.0

NPV at r = 20% 0.0 120.0 0.0 120.0

GNPV(r, 0) 0.0 120.0 0.0 120.0

The project's IRR is unique and equal to 20%. As all project present values are not negative in every period, the project is conventional.

Table 4.

A non-conventional project

Period 0 1 2 3

Cash flows -100.0 120.0 -100.0 110.0

NPV at r = 15.7% 0.0 115.7 -4.9 110.0

GNPV (15,4%, 0) 0.0 115.4 -4.6 110.0

The IRR of the project is equal to 15.73%. The present value in period 2 is negative therefore the project is non-conventional. Table 5 presents the calculation of the highest loan interest rate r* at which the project income covers

the loan and accrued interests without loss. As the rate r* is 15.4% and is not equal to the IRR, the project is non-conventional. While the GIRR(0) = 15.4% is the same as r*.

Table 5.

Cash flow statement (loan interest rate is 15.4%)

Period 0 1 2 3

Operating 0 104.6 0.0 95.4

Interest payments 0 -15.4 0.0 -14.6

Cash received from project 0 120.0 0 110.0

Investing -100 0 -100 0

Cash paid to project -100 0 -100 0

Financing 100 -100.0 95.4 -95.4

Borrowing loan 100 0 95.4 0

Loan repayment 0 -100.0 0 -95.4

Debt balance 100 0 95.4 0

3.3. A project without IRR

Let us consider a non-conventional project without an IRR (Table 6).

Table 6.

A non-conventional project without an IRR

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

Period 0 1 3

Cash flows -100.0 195.0 -100.0

NPV at r = -5% (no the IRR) -5.5 89.7 -100.0

GNPV(-5%,0) 0.0 95.0 -100.0

As the project does not have an IRR, it is non-conventional. Table 7. Cash flow statement (the loan interest rate is -5%)

Period 0 1 2

Operating 0 200.0 0

Interest payments 0 5.0 0

Cash received from project 0 195.0 0

Investing -100 0 -100

Cash paid to project -100 0 -100

Financing 100 -100.0 0

Borrowing loan 100 0 0

Loan repayment 0 -100.0 0

Debt balance 100 0 0

The loan interest rate r* at which the project income covers the project outflows is —5% (Table 7). Therefore r* is the rate of return of the project. An IRR does not exist, while the GIRR(0) = -5% is the same as r*.

Conclusion

Generally, all projects with cash flows having multiple changes in sign are referred to as non-conventional projects. That is just a property, but not a definition of a non-conventional project. Most economists consider the same sign of the present (or future) value of a project at the rate equal to the IRR to be a sufficient condition (attribute) of a conventional project. However, the determination of conventional and non-conventional projects has not been formulated yet.

It is known that non-conventional projects have problems with determination of IRR (a multiple-valued IRR or no real-valued IRR at all). On the other hand, if a project has a single IRR, this does not mean that the project in question is conventional. The IRR for a conventional project is its rate of return. Therefore, it is logical to conclude with a definition that the project is conventional if the IRR is the rate of return, and conversely, if the IRR is not the rate of return, the project is non-conventional. However, the rate of return of a non-conventional project cannot be determined within the framework of the NPV method. Generalization of the NPV to the GNPVby using two different rates when attracting and reinvesting funds instead of a single rate allows us to determine the rate of return of a non-conventional project.

This paper presents a mathematical determination of the rate of return for an investment project of any type and proves that in the case of a conventional project the rate of return is the IRR, while in the case of a non-conventional project it is the GIRR. The necessary and sufficient conditions of the conventional and non-conventional projects have been formulated. We hope that application of the proposed methodology to investment project profitability assessment will simplify calculation processes and help to avoid possible errors resulting from the imperfections of the NPV method. ■

References

1. Brealey R.A., Myers S.C. (2003) Principles of corporate finance. 7th Ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.

2. Brigham E.F., Gapenski L.C. (1996) Intermediate financial management. Orlando, FL: Dryden Press.

3. Gronchi S. (1986) On investment criteria based on the internal rate of return. Oxford Economic Papers, no. 38 (1), pp. 174—180.

4. De Faro C., Soares L. (1978) A flexible sufficient condition for a unique non-negative internal rate of return. The Engineering Economist, no. 23, pp. 117-127.

5. Soper C.S. (1959) The marginal efficiency of capital: A further note. The Economic Journal, no. 69 (273), pp. 174-177.

6. Cannaday R.E., Colwell P.F., Paley H. (1986) Relevant and Irrelevant internal rates of return. The Engineering Economist, no. 32, pp. 17-38.

7. Bussey L.E., Eschenbach T.G. (1992) The economic analysis of industrial projects, 2nd Ed. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.

8. Teichroew D., Robichek A.A., Montalbano M. (1965) An analysis of criteria for investment and financing decisions under certainty. Management Science, no. 12 (3), pp. 150—179.

9. Bernhard R.H. (1979) A simpler internal rate of return uniqueness condition which dominates that of de Faro and Soares. The Engineering Economist, no. 24 (2), pp. 71—74.

10. Hajdasinski M.M. (1987) On relevant and irrelevant internal rates of return. The Engineering Economist, no. 32, pp. 347—353.

11. Hazen G.B. (2003) A new perspective on multiple internal rates of return. The Engineering Economist, no. 48, pp. 31—51.

12. Beaves R.G. (1988) Net present value and rate ofreturn: Implicit and explicit reinvestment assumptions. TheEngineeringEconomist, no. 33 (4), pp. 275-302.

13. Lohmann J.R. (1988) The IRR, NPV and the fallacy of the reinvestment rate assumption. The Engineering Economist, no. 33 (4), pp. 303-330.

14. Blaset Kastro (Kulakova) A.N., Kulakov N.Yu. (2013) Evaluation of non-conventional projects. The Engineering Economist, no. 52 (2), pp. 137-148.

15. Magni C.A. (2010) Average internal rate of return and investment decisions: A new perspective. The Engineering Economist, vol. 55, no. 2, pp. 150-181.

16. Eschenbach T.G., Nicholls G.M. (2012) Is PW useful for the lorie-savage oil pump problem? Proceedinggs of the IIEAnnual Conference & Expo 2012, ISERC, 19-23 May 2012, Orlando, Florida.

17. Blaset Kastro (Kulakova) A.N., Kulakov N.Yu. (2012) Capital budgeting technique for non-conventional projects. Proceedings of the IIE Annual Conference & Expo 2012, ISERC, 19-23 May 2012, Orlando, Florida.

18. Bierman H. (Jr.), Smidt S. (1993) The capital budgeting decision, 8th ed. New York: MacMillan.

19. Dearing D., Richard V.H. (2010) Project balances as division coefficients and implications for rate of return analysis. The Engineering Economist, vol. 55, no. 2, pp. 38-51.

Определения типичного и нетипичного проектов

А.Н. Бласет Кастро

кандидат экономических наук, консультант, Группа компаний «КомпьюЛинк» Адрес: 119607, г. Москва, Мичуринский проспект, д. 45 E-mail: [email protected]

Н.Ю. Кулаков

кандидат технических наук, финансовый директор, Инвестиционно-финансовая компания «Вента» Адрес: 125284, г. Москва, Ленинградский проспект, д. 31А, стр.1 E-mail: [email protected]

Аннотация

Понятие «нетипичный», «нестандартный» проект или «проект с нетипичными денежными потоками» введено в экономическую литературу после того, как было показано, что для некоторых проектов внутренняя нома доходности (internal rate of return, IRR) может иметь несколько значений или не существовать вовсе. Проект считается «типичным», если его денежный поток только один раз меняет знак, независимо от направления: с минуса на плюс или наоборот. Типичный проект имеет единственное значение IRR. Однако не все проекты с многократным изменением знака денежного потока являются «нетипичными», т.е. имеют проблемы с определением IRR. Поэтому теория рекомендует для определения типа проекта исследовать зависимость функции чистого дисконтированного дохода (net present value, NPV) от ставки дисконтирования на монотонность с целью выявления множественности или отсутствия IRR. С другой стороны, монотонность NPV и единс венное значение IRR не гарантируют того, что проект типичный. Более того, было показано, что доходность нетипичного проекта в рамках подхода NPV не может быть определена, а, следовательно, и понятие доходности не может быть сформулировано. Недавно был предложен метод обобщенной чистой приведенной стоимости (generalized net present value, GNPV), на основе которого может быть рассчитана доходность «нетипичного» проекта.

В данной статье сформулировано понятие доходности для инвестиционного проекта любого типа и доказана ее тождественность обобщенной внутренней норме доходности (generalized internal rate of return, GIRR), вытекающей из метода GNPV. Дается определение и формулируются необходимое и достаточное условия типичного и нетипичного проекта.

ИНФОРМАЦИОННЫЕ СИСТЕМЫ И ТЕХНОЛОГИИ В БИЗНЕСЕ

Ключевые слова: типичный инвестиционный проект, нетипичный инвестиционный проект, внутренняя норма доходности, чистый дисконтированный доход, обобщенный чистый дисконтированный доход.

Цитирование: Blaset Kastro A.N., Kulakov N.Yu. Definition of the concepts of conventional and non-conventional projects // Business Informatics. 2016. No. 2 (36). P. 16-23. DOI: 10.17323/1998-0663.2016.2.16.23.

Литература

1. Brealey R.A., Myers S.C. Principles of corporate finance. 7th Ed. New York: McGraw-Hill, 2003.

2. Brigham E.F., Gapenski L.C. Intermediate financial management. Orlando, FL: Dryden Press, 1996.

3. Gronchi S. On investment criteria based on the internal rate of return // Oxford Economic Papers. 1986. No. 38 (1). P. 174—180.

4. De Faro C., Soares L. A flexible sufficient condition for a unique non-negative internal rate of return // The Engineering Economist. 1978. No. 23. P. 117-127.

5. Soper C.S. The marginal efficiency of capital: A further note // The Economic Journal. 1959. No. 69 (273). P. 174-177.

6. Cannaday R.E., Colwell P.F., Paley H. Relevant and Irrelevant internal rates of return // The Engineering Economist. 1986. No. 32. P. 17-38.

7. Bussey L.E., Eschenbach T.G. The economic analysis of industrial projects. 2nd Ed. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1992.

8. Teichroew D., Robichek A.A., Montalbano M. An analysis of criteria for investment and financing decisions under certainty // Management Science. 1965. No. 12 (3). P. 150-179.

9. Bernhard R.H. A simpler internal rate of return uniqueness condition which dominates that of de Faro and Soares // The Engineering Economist. 1979. No. 24 (2). P. 71-74.

10. Hajdasinski M.M. On relevant and irrelevant internal rates of return // The Engineering Economist. 1987. No. 32. P. 347-353.

11. Hazen G.B. A new perspective on multiple internal rates of return // The Engineering Economist. 2003. No. 48. P. 31-51.

12. Beaves R.G. Net present value and rate of return: Implicit and explicit reinvestment assumptions // The Engineering Economist. 1988. No. 33 (4). P. 275-302.

13. Lohmann J.R. The IRR, NPV and the fallacy of the reinvestment rate assumption // The Engineering Economist. 1988. No. 33 (4). P. 303-330.

14. Blaset Kastro (Kulakova) A.N., Kulakov N.Yu. Evaluation of non-conventional projects // The Engineering Economist. 2013. No. 52 (2). P. 137-148.

15. Magni C.A. Average internal rate of return and investment decisions: A new perspective // The Engineering Economist. 2010. Vol. 55. No. 2. P. 150-181.

16. Eschenbach T.G., Nicholls G.M. Is PW useful for the lorie-savage oil pump problem? // Proceedinggs of the IIE Annual Conference & Expo 2012, ISERC, 19-23 May 2012, Orlando, Florida.

17. Blaset Kastro (Kulakova) A.N., Kulakov N.Yu. Capital budgeting technique for non-conventional projects // Proceedings of the IIE Annual Conference & Expo 2012, ISERC, 19-23 May 2012, Orlando, Florida.

18. Bierman H. (Jr.), Smidt S. The capital budgeting decision. 8th ed. New York: MacMillan, 1993.

19. Dearing D., Richard V.H. Project balances as division coefficients and implications for rate of return analysis // The Engineering Economist. 2010. Vol. 55. No.2. P. 38-51.

БИЗНЕС-ИНФОРМАТИКА № 2(36) - 2016

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.