Научная статья на тему 'The Synergy and Cycle Values in Regional Innovation Systems: The Case of Norway'

The Synergy and Cycle Values in Regional Innovation Systems: The Case of Norway Текст научной статьи по специальности «Экономика и бизнес»

CC BY-NC-ND
265
92
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
Журнал
Форсайт
Scopus
ВАК
RSCI
ESCI
Область наук
Ключевые слова
Triple Helix / knowledge base / innovations / synergy / cycles / regional innovation system / regions of Norway

Аннотация научной статьи по экономике и бизнесу, автор научной работы — Inga Ivanova

The innovation capacity of a system can be measured as the synergy in interactions among its parts. Synergy can be considered as a consequence of negative entropies among three parts of the system. We analyze the development of synergy value in the Norwegian innovation system in terms of mutual information among geographical, sectorial, and size distributions of firms. We use three different techniques for the evaluation of the evolution of synergy over time: rescaled range analysis, DFT, and geographical synergy decomposition. The data was provided by Statistics Norway for all Norwegian firms registered in the database between 2002 and 2014. The results suggest that the synergy at the level of both the country and its seven regions show non-chaotic oscillatory behavior which resonates in a set of natural frequencies. The finding of a set of frequencies implies a complex Triple-Helix structure, composed of many elementary triple helices, which can be theorized in terms of a fractal TH manifold.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.

Текст научной работы на тему «The Synergy and Cycle Values in Regional Innovation Systems: The Case of Norway»

The Synergy and Cycle Values in Regional Innovation Systems: The Case of Norway

Inga Ivanova

Research Fellow, Institute for Statistical Studies and Economics of Knowledge, inga.ivanova@hse.ru

National Research University Higher School of Economics (NRU HSE), 20 Myasnitskaya str.,

Moscow 101000, Russian Federation

0ivind Strand

Professor, Department of International Business, oivind.strand@ntnu.no Norwegian University of Science and Technology (NTNU) Alesund, PO Box 1517, 6025 Aalesund, Norway

Loet Leydesdorff

Professor, Amsterdam School of Communications Research (ASCoR), loet@leydesdorff.net University of Amsterdam, PO Box 15793, 1001 NG Amsterdam, The Netherlands

Abstract

The innovation capacity of a system can be measured as the synergy in interactions among its parts. Synergy can be considered as a consequence of negative entropies among three parts of the system. We analyze the development of synergy value in the Norwegian innovation system in terms of mutual information among geographical, sectorial, and size distributions of firms. We use three different techniques for the evaluation of the evolution of synergy over time: rescaled range analysis, DFT, and

geographical synergy decomposition. The data was provided by Statistics Norway for all Norwegian firms registered in the database between 2002 and 2014. The results suggest that the synergy at the level of both the country and its seven regions show non-chaotic oscillatory behavior which resonates in a set of natural frequencies. The finding of a set of frequencies implies a complex Triple-Helix structure, composed of many elementary triple helices, which can be theorized in terms of a fractal TH manifold.

Keywords: Triple Helix; knowledge base; innovations; synergy; cycles; regional innovation system; regions of Norway.

Citation: Ivanova I., Strand 0., Leydesdorff L. (2019) The Synergy and Cycle Values in Regional Innovation Systems: The Case of Norway. Foresight and STI Governance, vol. 13, no 1, pp. 48-61. DOI: 10.17323/25002597.2019.1.48.61

The cyclical behavior of economic variables has been a research topic since the time of Schum-peter [Schumpeter, 1939], Kuznets [Kuznets, 1930], and Kondratieff [Kondratieff, 1935]. Recently, Lucraz [Lucraz, 2013] analyzed innovation cycles in a finite, discrete R&D game, concluding that strategic interactions among firms are sufficient for generating cycles. De Groot and Franses investigated cycles in basic innovations [de Groot, Franses, 2008, 2009] and more generally socioeconomic cycles [de Groot, Franses, 2012]. These authors concluded that there seems to be a common set of cycles across a number of socioeconomic variables.

The regional dimensions of business cycles were investigated by Dixon and Shepherd [Dixon, Shepherd, 2001, 2013], who filtered the data in terms of trends, cycles, and noise, and thus were able to show that similarities in cycles can be explained by the regional industry structure and the sizes of regions. Various techniques, such as autoregressive growth-rated models [Hodrick-Prescott, 1997] and frequency filter models, have been used to analyze cyclic data [Dixon, Shepherd, 2013]. From another perspective, fractal statistics and rescaled range (R/S) analysis were used to analyze cycles in various processes in nature [Feder, 1988; Froyland, 1992]. These techniques were developed to analyze regional economic fluctuations by considering a variety of factors that might explain the cyclical movements. From this viewpoint, it is interesting to explore whether synergies behave like business cycles and therefore one must ask whether business cycles may comprise a component of synergy. Previous studies did not account for the synergy of economic interactions. If synergy also evolves in cycles, then it can be considered an additional factor of economic fluctuations. The core research questions of the present paper regarding temporal synergy evolution are as follows: how do the synergies evolve? Can they be analyzed as trend-like, chaotic, oscillatory, or perhaps some other functional dependency? Do synergy values affect temporal evolution? In other words: is there a difference in synergy evolution between configurations with high and low synergy? Can numerical indicators of synergy evolution be provided?

Synergy in Innovation Systems

In a series of studies, we measured the synergy of a Triple Helix (TH) system as the reduction of uncertainty using mutual information among the three dimensions of firm sizes, the technological knowledge bases of firms, and geographical locations.1 In these studies, we obtained maps of synergy distributions across territories. However, having only static measurement results, one is unable to answer questions

such as those concerning the evolution of synergy over time. Does the synergy value affect the temporal evolution of the synergy in a system? Note that a TH system cannot be static [Etzkowitz, Leydesdorff, 2000], rather it is an ever-evolving system. This evolution can generate uncertainty or the reduction of uncertainty. Does the synergy in a system also evolve over time?

The innovation capacity of a system, for example, can be measured as the synergy of interactions among its parts. Both social and biological ecosystems can be expected to flourish and even proliferate if uncertainty in the relations among the constituent parts of the system is reduced [Ulanowicz, 1986]. From this perspective, the Triple Helix (TH) model of university-industry-government relations serves as a specific example of the innovation system. Synergy refers to the interactions among two or more parts, so that the combined effect of this interaction exceeds the sum of individual effects. Synergy is based upon the coherent actions of a system's parts, which means that these actions depend upon one another. In terms of statistical mechanics, this means that the system becomes more organized, or in other words, more ordered. The more ordered the system is, the more coherent are the interactions between the parts of the system.

Entropy can be used as an indicator of order. Entropy measures the degree to which the system is ordered with respect to different possible system states. The system configuration is not limited by actual realized states. In addition to actual system states, the system can potentially have other states (which may be realized in the future). We refer to the latter as virtual states. The difference between the maximum possible entropy and the actual entropy realized by the system provides a measure of order. This measure can be increased either by reducing the actual entropy (leaving the maximal entropy unchanged) or by increasing the maximal entropy (i.e., increasing the number of virtual states) while actual entropy remains unchanged.

For example, in the 19th century one attributed approximately 20% of the available funds to developing mechanical engineering technology. When the same amount of funds is attributed to mechanical engineering technology in the 21st century, the percentage is unchanged, but the number of virtual options (supported by the corresponding technologies) in the 21st century exceeds that of the 19th century. In addition to mechanical engineering, one has now access to computer technology, biotechnology, nanotechnolo-gy, and so on. Hence, the ordering in the economy of the 21st century exceeds that of the 19th century econ-

1 Netherlands [Leydesdorff et al., 2006], Germany [Leydesdorff, Fritsch, 2006], Hungary [Lengyel, Leydesdorff, 2011], Norway [Strand, Leydesdorff, 2013], Sweden [Leydesdorff, Strand, 2013], Japan [Leydesdorff, Yan Sun, 2009], South Korea [Kwon et al., 2012], West Africa [Megnigbeto, 2013], China [Ye et al., 2013; Leydesdorff, Zhou, 2014], and Russia [Leydesdorff et al., 2015].

omy due to additional options that provide additional flexibility, adaptability, and competitive advantages. Information-theoretical probabilistic entropy as described by Shannon's mathematical theory of communications follows the definition of Boltzman's entropy [Shannon, 1948]. Communicating sub-systems can provide additional options that can be measured as mutual information and this may lead to a reduction in uncertainty at the system level. This reduction of uncertainty can be considered a measure of synergy2, which can be expressed in negative bits of information using the Shannon formula [Abramson, 1963; Theil, 1972; Leydesdorff, 1995].3 In this study, we use the entropy approach to measure yearly synergy in the Norwegian innovation system during the period 2002-2014. Longitudinal synergy data provide a picture of temporal synergy evolution. The choice of the Norwegian system is guided by the availability of data. However, the method is generic and can be applied to any system that meets the criterion of possessing three (or more) analytically independent parts.

Methodology and Data

Methodology

The interaction between two system parts can be numerically evaluated using the tenets of Shannon's information theory by measuring mutual information as the reduction of uncertainty at the system level. In the case of three interacting parts, the mutual information in a configuration can be defined by analogy to mutual information between two parts, as follows [Abramson, 1963; McGill, 1954):

Ty = H, + H, + H„ - H„ - H„

■ H23 + H123 ■

(1)

the numbers of relevant events in subdivisions. For example, if N is the total number of firms, n..k is the number of firms in the i-th county, the j-th organizational level (defined by the number of staff employed), and the k-th technology group. Then n. and n.. can be calculated as follows:

n,

I 71;

ijk

(4)

A set of L mutual information values for a certain time period, considered a finite time signal, can be spectrally analyzed with the help of the discrete Fourier transformation [Analog Devices, 2000]:

Tz

Here

I'io PiO

(5)

F0 = A; F;(w) = Bt cos(2nlw/L) + Dism(2nlw/L) (6)

The Fourier transformation by itself cannot provide us with information regarding synergy evolution except the values of the spectral coefficients: A, B{ and Dl. Because the aggregate (country-related) synergy Ts is determined by additive entropy measures (Equation 1), it can also be decomposed as a sum of partial (county-related) synergies T1, ■■■Tn:4

T. + T2 + ■■■T ■

12 n

(7)

So that each partial synergy can be written in the same form as Equation 5:

L/2

1=0

L/2

Ti^fuW. T2 = ^f2lW ... rL=2/1L(w), (8) 1=0

L/2

i=0

Here:

Here H, H , H. denote probabilistic entropy mea- foi = /mO) = Ki cos(2nlw/L) + dnlsm(2nlw/L)

sures in one, two, and three dimensions:

Hi = ~YPil°d2Pi

i

Hij = ~TPiJlo92Plj

ij

Hm = -Y.Pmlod2Pïjk

(2)

The values of p represent the probabilities, which can be defined as the ratio of the corresponding frequency distributions:

Pi - 1/jv ; PU = N ; Pijk = t;k/N ,

(3)

N is the total number of events, and n, n , n , denote

if ijk

After substituting Equations (5) and (8) into (7) and re-grouping the terms, one obtains:

Fi(w) = fu(w) + /2i(w)+.. +fnl(w) (9)

Leydesdorff and Ivanova [Ivanova, Leydesdorff, 2014a] showed that mutual information in three dimensions is equal to mutual redundancy (T123 = R123). Aggregated redundancy can equally be decomposed as a sum of partial redundancies, corresponding to the geographical, structural, or technological dimensions of the innovation system under study. Mutual redundancy changes over time, so one can write:

«123(0 = «i(i) + «2(i) + ■■■ + Rn(t) (10)

2 In fact, it is a measure of system ordering that is the result of the synergy of interactions between the system parts

3 A problem in applying Shannon's formula to trilateral and higher-order dimensional interactions is that mutual information is then a finitely additive measure [Yeung, 2008; Leydesdorff, 2010]. A negative information measure cannot comply with Shannon's definition of information [Krippendorff, 2009a, b]. This contradiction can be solved by considering mutual information to be different from mutual redundancy [Leydesdorff, Ivanova, 2014]. In the three-dimensional case, however, mutual information is equal to mutual redundancy and, thus, mutual information in three dimensions can be considered a Triple-Helix indicator of synergy in university-industry-government relations [Leydesdorff et al., 2014].

4 This decomposition is different from that used in our previous studies [Leydesdorff, Strand, 2013; Strand, Leydesdorff, 2013].

In another context, Ivanova and Leydesdorff [Ivanova, Leydesdorff, 2014b] expressed a redundancy that can be obtained as follows (i= 1, 2 ... n):

Ri = a[ + b'i соs(r[t) + d-cos(r£t)

(11)

The oscillating function in Equation (11) can be considered a natural frequency of the TH system. This natural frequency is far from fitting the observed redundancy values for R123. However, real data for the definite time interval can be fit with the help of the discrete Fourier transformation, comprising a finite set of frequencies. Each frequency in the set composing Equation (10) can be considered a natural frequency of the TH system:

«123 = A + Zk=i(ßfccos(fei) + DfcSin(fct))

(12)

Comparing Equations (12) and (11), one can approximate the empirical data for three-dimensional redundancy as a sum of partial redundancies corresponding to the frequencies that are multiples of the basic frequency: w, 2w, 3w ... etc.

R123 = R1 + R2 + - + RN •

(13)

In other words, a TH system can be represented as a string resonating in a set of natural frequencies with different amplitudes. Frequency-related amplitudes, which can be defined as modules of the corresponding Fourier coefficients, can be considered the spectral structure of the TH system. Absolute values of the Fourier-series coefficients can be defined as follows:

Ct = V (fif + Df ) (14)

These coefficients determine the relative contributions of the harmonic functions with corresponding frequencies to the aggregate redundancy (R123 in Equation (12)).

Transmission Power and Efficiency

Following Mêgnigbêto [Megnigbeto, 2014, p. 287], the transmission power of synergy can be calculated according to the following formula:

T =

4 =

т2 =

tgot

H GOT-H G ~Ho-Ht

tgot

H got

0

if Tgot <0

if TGot >0, (15) if TG0T = 0

The transmission power is designed to measure the efficiency of mutual information. While the transmission defines the total amount of configurational information, the transmission power represents the share of synergy in the system relative to its size. For positive transmission values, it is simply the overlapping area-total area ratio in a corresponding Venn diagram. Mêgnigbêto [Mêgnigbêto, 2014, p. 290] ar-

gued that "... with such indicators, a same system may be compared over time; different systems may also be compared."

Characteristics of Norwegian Regions

The regions in Norway are illustrated in Figure 1. Norway is divided into 19 counties at the Nomenclature of Territorial Units (NUTS) level 3 and seven regions at NUTS 2. These regions are the geographical units of analysis in this study.

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

The characteristics of the seven regions are provided in Table 1. Data on the population and the numbers of firms are provided by Statistics Norway [Statistics Norway, 2015]. The most populated area is the capital region Oslo og Akershus (OA), the sparsely populated and areas dominated by primary industries are found inland (Hedmark og Oppland (HO)) and in the north (Nord-Norge (NN)). The center of the oil and gas industry is in Agder and Rogaland (AR) in the southwest, with Stavanger as the most important city. The region of Trondelag (TR) includes the city of Trondheim where the main technical university and several research institutes are located, as well as agricultural areas in the northern part of the region. The region Sor-0stlandet (SE) is composed of several counties with a diverse industry structure. Vestlandet (WE) is the center for marine and maritime related industries in Norway.

According to the Regional Innovation Scoreboard 2015 [European Commission, 2015], OA, WE, TR, and NN are classified as innovation followers, whereas HO, SE, and AR are classified as moderate innovators. The results from an analysis of TH synergy based on register data from 2008 are also given in Table 1. From this it can be observed that synergy is highest in the regions Vestlandet (WE) and Sor-0stlandet (SE). Low levels of synergy are found in Oslo and Akershus (OA), Hedemark og Oppland (HO) and Trondelag (TR). Moderate levels are found in Agder and Roga-land (AR) and Nord-Norge (NN).

Data

In order to compare the industry structure in various regions, we use a firm-based version of the Krugman index of dissimilarity [Krugman, 1991, 1993; Dixon, Shepherd, 2013].

For each industry sector i, data on the number of firms in region A; XA. and XB. are provided. The total number of firms in each region is: XA and XB. The dissimilarity between the industry sectors in the two regions can then be calculated as:

KIDM= X

XjB \XB J

(16)

A value of zero indicates that the industry structures in the two regions are equal. The opposite, when the

Table 1. Characteristics of Norwegian Regions

Regional Innovation Scoreboard 2015 Number of firms Population TH synergy in mbits

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Oslo og Akershus (OA) Follower 132 262 1 232 575 -7.88

Hedmark og Oppland (HO) Moderate 44 847 383 960 -9.58

S0r-0stlandet (SE) Moderate 99 157 976 550 -18.06

Agder og Rogaland (AR) Moderate 72 437 761 946 -14.05

Vestlandet (WE) Follower 85 754 884 246 -22.10

Tr0ndelag (TR) Follower 45 131 445 785 -9.84

Nord-Norge (NN) Follower 47 114 480 740 -15.94

Source: compiled by the authors based on [European Commission, 2015] (column 1), [Statistics Norway, 2015] (columns 2 and 3), [Strand, Leydesdorff, 2013] (column 4).

two structures have nothing in common would give an index value of 2.

Norwegian establishment data were retrieved from the database of Statistics Norway [Statistics Norway, 2015]. The data include time series of Norwegian companies during the period 2002-2014 and encompass approximately 400,000 firms per year. The data include the number of establishments in the three relevant dimensions: geographical (G), organizational (O), and technological (T).

As noted, seven regions are distinguished in the geographical dimension. In the organizational dimension, establishments are subdivided with reference to the different numbers of employees by eight groups: no-one employed; 1-4 employees; 5-9 employees; 10-19 employees; 20-49 employees; 50-99 employees; 100-249 employees; and 250 or more em-

ployees. The number of employees can be expected to correlate with the establishment's organizational structure.

The technological dimension indicates domains of economic activity. The data during the period 20022008 were organized according to the NACE Rev. 1.1 classification [Eurostat, 2002] and the data during the period 2009-2014 were organized according to the NACE Rev. 2 classification [Eurostat, 2008]. Some of the criteria for the construction of the new classification were reviewed: there is no one-to-one correspondence between NACE Rev. 1.1 (with 17 sections and 62 divisions) and NACE Rev. 2 (with 21 sections and 88 divisions) [Eurostat, 2008]. To correctly merge the NACE Rev. 1.1 and NACE Rev. 2 data, one has to turn to a higher level of aggregation (Table 2) containing 10 classes [Eurostat, 2007].

Figure 1. Norwegian Regions (NUTS 2)

Figure 2. Summary of the Development of TH Synergy at the National Level for Norway (in bits of information)

Vestlandet (WE)

""Trandelag (TR) " Hedmark og Oppland (HO)

Oslo og Akershus (OA) *S0r-0stlandet (SE)

Agder og Rogaland (AR)

Source: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Counties_of_Norway.

-0.0105

-0.0135

oooooooo^^^^^ ooooooooooooo

(N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N

Years

Source: authors' calculations.

Table 2. Correspondence of High-Level Aggregation (ISIC ver. 4) to NACE Rev 1.1 and NACE Rev. 2 Classifications

High-level aggregation ISIC Rev.4 NACE Rev.2 NACE Rev.1.1

1 1-5; 74.14; 92.72 A 1, 2, 5; Agriculture, forestry and fishing 1; 2; 5; 74.14; 92.72; A 01 Agriculture, hunting and related service activities 02 Forestry, logging and related service activities

B 05 Fishing, fish farming and related service activities

2 10-41; 01.13; 01.41; 02.01; 51.31; 51.34; 52.74; 72.50; 90.01; 90.02; 90.03 B 10-14 Mining and quarrying 10-14 C CA 10 Mining of coal and lignite, extraction of peat CA 11 Extraction of crude petroleum and natural gas, service activities incidental to oil and gas etc. CA 12 Mining of uranium and thorium ores CB 13 Mining of metal ores CB 14 Other mining and quarrying

C 15-37 Manufacture 15-36; 01.13; 01.41; 02.01; 10.10; 10.20; 10.30; 51.31; 51.34; 52.74; 72.50; D DA 15 Manufacture of food products and beverages DA 16 Manufacture of tobacco DB 17 Manufacture of textiles DB 18 Manufacture of wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur DC 19 Tanning and dressing of leather, manufacture of luggage, handbags, saddlery, harness and footwear DD 20 Manufacture of wood and of products of wood and cork, except furniture DE 21 Manufacture of pulp, paper and paper products DE 22 Publishing, printing and reproduction of recorded media DF 23 Manufacture of coke, refined petroleum products and nuclear fuel DG 24 Manufacture of chemicals and chemical products DH 25 Manufacture of rubber and plastic products DI 26 Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products DJ 27 Manufacture of basic metals DJ 28 Manufacture of fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment DK 29 Manufacture of machinery and equipment n.e.c. DL 30 Manufacture of office machinery and computers DL 31 Manufacture of electrical machinery and apparatus n.e.c. DL 32 Manufacture of radio, television and communication equipment and apparatus DL 33 Manufacture of medical, precision and optical instruments, watches and clocks DM 34 Manufacture of motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers DM 35 Manufacture of other transport equipment DN 36 Manufacture of furniture, manufacturing n.e.c. DN 37 Recycling

D 40 Electricity, gas and steam 40; E 40 Electricity, gas, steam and hot water supply 41 Collection, purification and distribution of water

E (+4) 41 Water supply, sewerage, waste 41; 37; 90 14.40; 23.30; 24.15; 37.10; 37.20; 40.11; 90.01; 90.02; 90.03

3 3 45; 20.30; 25.23; 28.11; 28.12; 29.22; 70.11; F 45 Construction 45; 20.30; 25.23; 28.11; 28.12; 29.22; 70.11; F 45 Construction

4 50-63; 11.10; 64.11; 64.12; G 50-52 Wholesale and retail trade: repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles 50- 52; G 50 Sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles, retail sale of automotive fuel 51 Wholesale trade and commission trade, except motor vehicles and motorcycles 52 Retail trade, except motor vehicles and motorcycles, Repair of personal and household goods

I 55 Accommodation and food service activities 55; H 55 Hotels and restaurants

H 60-63 Transportation and storage 60-63; 11.10; 50.20; 64.11; 64.12; I 60 Land transport, transport via pipelines 61 Water transport 62 Air transport 63 Supporting and auxiliary transport activities, activities of travel agencies 64 Post and telecommunications

5 64, 72; 22.11; 22.12; 22.13; 22.15; 22.22; 30.02; 92.11; 92.12; 92.13; 92.20; J 64,72 Information and communication 64; 72; 22.11; 22.12; 22.13; 22.15; 22.22; 30.02; 92.11; 92.12; 92.13; 92.20;

Table 2 (continued)

6 65-67; 74.15; K 65-67 Financial and insurance activities 65- 67; 74.15; J 65 Financial intermediation, except insurance and pension funding 66 Insurance and pension funding, except compulsory social security 67 Activities auxiliary to financial intermediation

7 70; L 70 Real estate activities 70; K 70 Real estate activities 71 Renting of machinery and equipment without operator and of personal and household goods 72 Computers and related activities 73 Research and development 74 Other business activities

8 71-74; 01.41; 05.01; 45.31; 63.30; 63.40; 64.11; 70.32; 75.12; 75.13; 85.20; 90.03; 92.32; 92.34; 92.40; 92.62; 92.72; M (+10) 71,73 Professional, scientific and technical activities 73; 74; 05.01; 63.40; 85.20; 92.40;

N (-2) 74 Administrative and support service activities 71; 01.41; 45.31; 63.30; 64.11; 70.32; 74.50;74.87; 75.12; 75.13; 90.03; 92.32; 92.34; 92.62; 92.72;

9 75-85; 63.22; 63.23; 74.14; 92.34; 92.62; 93.65; O 75 Public administration and defense: compulsory social security 75; L 75 Public administration and defense, compulsory social security

P 80 Education 80; 63.22; 63.23; 74.14; 92.34; 92.62; 93.65; M 80 Education

Q 85, 90, 91 Human health and social work activities 85; 75.21; N 85 Health and social work

10 92-99; 01.50;29.32; 32.20; 36.11; 36.12; 36.14; 52.71; 52.72; 52.73; 52.74; 72.50; 75.14; 91; R 92 Arts, entertainment and recreation 92; 75.14; O 90 Sewage and refuse disposal, sanitation and similar activities 91 Activities of membership organizations n.e.c. 92 Recreational, cultural and sporting activities 93 Other service activities

S (+2) 93 Other service activities 93; 91; 01.50;29.32; 32.20; 36.11; 36.12; 36.14; 52.71; 52.72; 52.73; 52.74; 72.50;

T 95 Households as employers activities 95; P 95 Activities of households with employed persons

U 99 Extraterritorial organizations and bodies 99 Q 99 Extra-territorial organizations and bodies

Source: compiled by the authors based on [Eurostat, 2007, 2008].

Results

Descriptive Statistics

Regional synergy is calculated as a sum of the synergies at the county level in accordance with Equation (7). The results of the calculations during the period 2002-2014 (in bits of information) are shown in Figure 2 for the national level and Figure 3 for the regional level.

The synergy at the national level follows a general lateral trend with alternating upwards and downwards sectors. More negative T(uig) is observed until 2004, then a decrease in synergy takes place until the economic crisis in 2008, after which a recovery is present where synergy shows a positive trend. As

can be seen from Figure 3, the country synergy is in large part shaped by the synergy in the capital region OA5. The other six Norwegian districts demonstrate relatively stable development. These regions are subdivided into two visually separated strands with respect to synergy values: HO, AR, TR, and WE, SE, NN.

Fluctuations in synergy data can be interpreted as synergy cycles. Like economic cycles, synergy cycles indicate endogenous characteristics of an innovation system such as cyclic oscillations of the market system [Morgan, 1991]. An alternative to considering the fluctuations as cycles would be to consider them the result of noise in the data; this will be clarified this in the next section.

5 In [Strand, Leydesdorff, 2013], the synergy calculations were based upon municipal data resulting in a singularity in the capital of the country (Oslo). In this paper, the calculations are based upon the contributions of the counties to the national level, allowing the contribution of the capital to be specified.

Figure 3. Partial Ternary Synergy for the Seven Regions of Norway (in bits of information)

Figure 5. Transmission Power t for Norwegian Regions (in relative units) during the Period 2002-2014

о 5

-0.001

-0.002

-0.003

-0.004

-0.005

-0.006

0.09

OOOOOOOOO^^^^^

oooooooooooooo

<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N

Years

Hedmark og Oppland Agder og Rogaland Trendelag

S0r-0stlandet Nord-Norge Vestlandet Oslo og Akershus

OOOOOOOO^^^^^

ooooooooooooo

<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N<N

Years

Nord-Norge Agder og Rogaland Oslo og Akershus

S0r-0stlandet

Vestlandet

Tr0ndelag

Hedmark og Oppland

Source: authors' calculations.

Source: authors' calculations.

0

Transmission Power and Efficiency

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

The transmission power at national and regional level are given in Figures 4 and 5.

As can be seen from Figure 4, transmission power shows stability with a shift in 2008. A linear trend line would have indicated a weak growing efficiency of the Norwegian innovation system at the national level. Figure 5 shows that the rate of efficiency growth is most accentuated in the NN and HO regions. The

OA capital region with the highest synergy values possesses medium transmission power. By comparing the results for synergy and transmission power at the regional level, it is shown that the high synergy in the U-I-G interaction does not necessarily imply the most efficient innovation system construct. Comparing transmission power at the national level in Figure 4 with the synergy in Figure 2 shows slowly increased transmission power and accordingly in-

Figure 6. Percentage of Average Efficiency Deviation for the Seven Norwegian Regions during the Period 2002-2014 (in percentages)

Oslo og Akershus Hedmark og Oppland S0r-0stlandet Agder og Rogaland Vestlandet Tr0ndelag Nord-Norge

-2 -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 K, %

Source: authors' calculations.

1 1.5

Figure 4. Summary of Norway Transmission Power t (in relative units) during the Period 2002-2014

0.07 -i-

0.06---- —

0.05----^-

0.04--

0.03--

0.02--

0.01--

0--

OOOOOOOO-H-H-H-H-H

OOOOOOOOOOOOO

(N(N(N(N(N(N(N(N(N(N(N(N(N

Years

Source: authors' calculations.

Figure 8. Modules of Fourier Series Coefficients C versus Frequency for Summary Ternary Synergy at the National Level (in bits of information)

Figure 7. Percentage of Average Synergy Deviation for Norwegian Regions during the Period 2002-2014 (in percentages)

Oslo og Akershus Hedmark og Oppland Sor-0stlandet Agder og Rogaland Vestlandet Trondelag Nord-Norge

0 1

P %

3 4

0.016 0.014 0.012 0.01 S 0.008 0.006 0.004 0.002 0

I.I

Source: authors' calculations.

1 2 3 Source: authors' calculations.

4 n

2

5

6

7

creasing synergy over time. The dip in 2008 is more pronounced for static synergy data than for the dynamic measure of transmission power. At the regional level, the same patterns are most pronounced in NN, HO, WE, and to some extent in SE. A decreasing value in transmission can be found in TR, whereas OA and NN show more fluctuating development. The percentage of the average efficiency deviation:

K = Ti™~fiav x ioo%, (17)

T-iav

where Tiav is the efficiency for the ¿-th region averaged over the period 2002-2014; ^iav is the summary average efficiency averaged over all of the regions (Figure 6), and the percentage of average synergy deviation

P = Tlav-Tlav x 100o/O; (18)

Tiav

where Tiav is the synergy for ¿-th county averaged over the period 2002-2014; and Tiav is the summary average synergy averaged over all of the regions (Figure 8). Efficiency is above the country average in OA, NN and AR. Synergy is above average in OA, NN, WE. When comparing the figures one can observe that the efficiency and synergy peaks do not coincide: regions with the highest synergy values are not always the most efficient. While for OA, the above-average synergy value may indicate that the increase in synergy was caused by increased transmission power, in NN, on the contrary, relatively low synergy is accompanied by the highest value for efficiency. Spearman rank correlation between the percentages of synergy and the efficiency values is 0.64 (n.s.). This value of the Spearman rank correlation indicates that there is a monotonic dependence between the

two variables. This sheds light on the need for more in-depth research on the parameters influencing innovation systems with respect to synergy-efficiency ratios.

As a next step, a deeper look is taken into the structure of the fluctuating behavior of the aggregate redundancy time series. First, the discrete Fourier transformation is implemented in accordance with Equation (5). The inputs of different frequency modes for Norway's synergy (w, 2w, 3w, 4w, 5w, 6w, 7w), calculated according to Equation (14), are shown in Figure 8. Each of the regional synergies can be mapped as fluctuations around an average value. Thus, the average values can be taken as the first terms in the corresponding Fourier decomposition describing non-fluctuating terms (f0. in Equation (8)). These average values form the synergy line specter. Having calculated the modules of the Fourier series coefficients, which are the measures of different frequency modes, as well as the line specter synergy values, modules versus synergy values can be mapped. Because the real-number data (during the period 2002-2014) are addressed, then, due to the symmetry of DFT coefficients, only half the number of input data with differing frequency components (the first six) can be specified. C1 corresponds to a 12-year cycle; C2 to a 6-year cycle, and similarly the seventh component (C7) corresponds to the 1-year cycle, which is the highest frequency that can be calculated with this method. In Figure 9 synergies (in bits of information) are plotted versus frequency amplitudes for the seven regions. It can be seen from the figure that the various Fourier components have very high values in Oslo and Ak-ershus (OA), indicating that synergy does not possess strong cyclic components at the frequencies observed. Vestlandet (WE) is the region with second largest amplitudes for Fourier components. A similar pattern

2019

Figure 9. Modules of Fourier Series Coefficients C versus Frequency for Seven Norwegian Regions (in bits of information)

Table 3. Spearman Rank Correlation between the Percentage of Average Synergy Deviation and Modules of Fourier Coefficients

0.016 0.014 0.012 0.01 0.008 0.006 0.004 0.002 0

■ Oslo og Akershus

■ Agder og Rogaland

■ Sor-0stlandet

Source: authors' calculations.

1

1 =1

■ I P ■ m mu ii i urn II E

Vestlandet Trondelag

Hedmark og Oppland Nord-Norge

with high values for the component is also found for Sor-0stlandet (SE), Vestlander (WE), and Nord Norge (NN). Hedemark og Oppland (HO), Agder og Rogaland (AR), and Trondelag (TR) have the least accentuated oscillation behavior. Nord-Norge (NN) in contrast with other six regions is the region with the most dominant second component. Nord-Norge, where fishing and related industries play a dominant role, is exposed to fluctuations in the high frequency component.

There is a monotone dependence between the modules of Fourier coefficients and the percentage of average synergy deviations for the Norwegian regions. The results of the Spearman correlation between these two values are provided in Table 3. In other words, the more synergetic is the system, the more strongly are the fluctuations of synergy expressed.

Spearman Rank Correlation

C1 C2 C3 C4 C5 C6 C7

rho 1 0.964 0.964 0.964 0.321 0.893 0.964

2-sided p-values 0.0004 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.498 0.012 0.003

S 1.243 2.0 2.0 2.0 38 6.0 2.0

Source: authors' calculations.

Previous studies of business cycles have shown that the Krugman dissimilarity index may be used to explain cyclic variations in regions [Dixon, Shepherd, 2013]. Regions with a high degree of similarity in the industry structure, which is indicated by a low Krug-man index, show similar cyclic patterns. The Krug-man index as defined in Equation (15) is calculated based on two-digit NACE codes and firm level data for 2015. The results are given in Table 4. As can be seen from this table, the capital region, Oslo and Akershus (OA), is most dissimilar compared to the other regions. The highest similarity (lowest index) is found between Vestlandet (WE) and Agder og Roga-land (AR), and between Sor-0stlandet (SE) and Ag-der og Rogaland (AR).

The degree of synergy fluctuation randomness can also be evaluated using R/S analysis [Hurst, 1951; Feder, 1988]. The standard algorithm and the calculation results are presented in Box 1. The Hurst rescaled range statistical measure H values in the range 0.5 < H < 1 indicate a persistent or trend-like behavior described by a monotone function. H = 0.5 corresponds to a completely chaotic time series behavior, like that of Brownian noise. Values in the range 0 < H < 0.5 indicate anti-persistent or oscillating behavior. The obtained Hurst exponent value, in our case H = 0.31, is well below 0.5 indicating a strongly expressed oscillating time series behavior. That is, the system-gener-

2

3

4

5

6

7

n

Table 4. Krugman Index of Dissimilarity in Industry Structure for Norwegian Regions

No. Oslo og Akershus Hedmark og Oppland S0r- 0stlandet Agder og Rogaland Vestlandet Tr0ndelag Nord-Norge

1 2 3 4 5 6 7

Oslo og Akershus (OA) 1 0 0.634 0.410 0.427 0.443 0.469 0.520

Hedmark og Oppland (HO) 2 0.634 0 0.333 0.333 0.370 0.231 0.397

S0r-0stlandet (S0) 3 0.410 0.333 0 0.147 0.200 0.247 0.313

Agder og Rogaland (AR) 4 0.427 0.370 0.147 0 0.124 0.216 0.284

Vestlandet (WE) 5 0.443 0.346 0.200 0.124 0 0.189 0.222

Tr0ndelag (TR) 6 0.469 0.231 0.247 0.216 0.189 0 0.275

Nord-Norge (NN) 7 0.520 0.397 0.313 0.284 0.222 0.275 0

Source: authors' calculations.

Box 1. The Hurst Method

The Hurst method is used to evaluate autocorrelations of the time series. It was first introduced by Hurst [Hurst, 1951] and was later widely used in fractal geometry [Feder, 1988]. The essence of the method is as follows [Quan, Rasheed, 2004]: For a given time series (T, T2,...TN),in our case, yearly ternary transmissions for a given time period, one can consistently perform the following steps:

a) calculate the mean m:

m = (A1)

b) calculate mean adjusted time series:

Yt — Tt — m (A2)

c) form cumulative deviate time series:

zt = HUrt (A3)

d) calculate range time series:

Rt = max(Z1( Z2,... Zt) - min(Zlf Z2,... Zt) (A4)

e) calculate standard deviation time series:

St = JjZhCTi-ny , (A5)

where

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

ft=\n=iTi (A6)

f) calculate rescaled range time series:

(%)t=| (A7)

In expressions (A2) - (A7) t = 1, 2...N. Under the supposition that:

(*/5)t = Ct» (A8)

the Hurst exponent H can be calculated by res-caled range (R/S) analysis and defined as linear regression slope of R/S vs. t in log-log scale. In our case H=0.0655 (see figure A1). Values of H = 0.5 indicate a random time series, such as Brownian noise. Values in the interval 0 < H < 0.5 indicate anti-persistent time series in which high values are likely to be followed by low values. This tendency is more pronounced the closer the value of H comes to zero. That is, one can expect oscillating behavior. Values in the interval 0.5 < H < 1 indicate a persistent time series. That is, the time series is likely to be monotoni-cally increasing or decreasing. The case H=0.0655 corresponds to oscillatory behavior.

Figure A1. R/S Analysis for Norwegian Synergy from 2002 to 2014

1.20 -

0.20

0.00 é-

0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00

t

Source: authors' calculations.

ated synergy evolves over time in non-chaotic cycles (similar to long-term and business cycles).

Summary and Conclusions

Having studied TH synergy evolution, the following conclusions can be made: first, TH synergy demonstrates non-chaotic oscillatory behavior. That is, one can study 'synergy cycles' as they do for economic and technological cycles. Second, TH systems can be considered to be composed of a set of oscillatory modes in terms of high and low frequency oscillations. From a theoretical perspective, TH systems are expected to have only a single oscillatory mode. The finding of a set of modes implies a complex TH structure, composed of many 'elementary' helices, which

can be theorized in terms of a fractal TH structure [Carayannis, Campbell, 2009; Ivanova, Leydesdorff, 2014a; Leydesdorff, Ivanova, 2016]. Third, oscillation amplitudes were found to be proportional to average synergy values. Thus, the synergy oscillations can be scaled with respect to the average synergies of TH constituent components. In summary, the TH structure (at the level of regions and nations) may be more complex than expected.

Three different techniques for the numerical evaluation of temporal synergy evolution in a three-dimensional system are used: R/S analysis, DFT, and geographical synergy decomposition. Briefly summarizing the results obtained from the study of the Norwegian innovation system, we can conclude that the

synergy time series exhibit cyclic structures of a non-random nature. This is important because synergy oscillations can be caused, in part, by system-inherent factors, and, in part, by external systemic factors. This feature should be taken into consideration by policy makers when developing related policies for innovation in areas under their sphere of competence, given that innovation efficiency is both locally and globally determined. It demonstrates how the various methods can be used for mapping the evolution of synergy. However, longer time series and shorter sampling intervals would be preferable, even though this involves large amounts of register data. It would then be possible to link the indicated synergy cycles to other and more well-established business cycles through the co-integration of the time series. This could shed new light on the synergy control mechanisms in a TH innovation system.

From a conceptual perspective, the synergy in TH innovation systems can be analyzed as a set of harmonic partials at the system's level, while an analytically "pure" TH system can be expected to contain only a single harmonic [Ivanova, Leydesdorff, 2014b]. The appearance of many oscillatory modes indicates a more complex and self-organized TH structure than was traditionally thought. For example, Norway's national innovation system can be presented as a geographically distributed network with nodes relating to corresponding regions and one should account for innovation systems at scales other than the national [Strand et al., 2016].

The synergy value is a monotonic function of frequency. Given that the frequency values are also a proxy of the speed of change of the corresponding frequency-related transmission parts (and otherwise, a proxy of volatility), one can expect frequency-related synergy volatility growth proportional to the value of synergy. This is the case for both transmission increases and decreases. In other words, the synergy in more coherently interacting systems grows faster than that in less coherent ones. In the case of decline, however, initially more coherent systems degrade faster. In other words, synergy formation is self-reinforcing, but so is its decay.

Policy Implications

The relative contribution of long-term frequencies increases with the increase of synergy values leading to a frequency shift. In other words, one can expect the synergy volatility to increase with synergy growth. This means that regions with high synergy values are expected to exhibit more fluctuations in synergy than

References

low-synergy regions, demonstrating strong range fluctuations in periods of boost or decline. Based on the various techniques used in this study, it would be possible to develop indicators to monitor the innovation systems' response to external shocks like the fall in oil prices in 2015 and the structural effect of various political measures like the Norwegian government's crisis interventions in the petroleum dependent region of Agder og Rogaland in 2016. Such indicators could guide the government towards carefully considering both the timing, the regional setting, and the time-scale of political measures. Government interventions at national level could amplify or dampen the synergy fluctuations depending on the actual region. Government interventions in regions dominated by one industry sector can have an un-desired effect if applied nationally or to regions with high industry activity. Regarding time scales, political measures should be designed to create long term (low frequency) positive economic effects rather than short term (high frequency) political effects.

Further Research

Another result refers to the distinction between the synergy of interactions within a TH system and the system's efficiency. One can conclude that these two measures are statistically correlated though they capture different kinds of information. The study of factors influencing these two important features of innovation systems is a topic of future research. This raises further research questions which are relevant to innovation studies. One can further focus the analysis from the region to the firm-size level. Assuming that the results remain the same, this may raise further research questions with respect to firm dynamics. According to Gibrat's Law for all firms in a given sector, however, the growth of a firm (i.e., the proportional change in the firm's size) is independent of its size [Gibrat, 1931]. The studies of a number of firms confirmed Gibrat's Law [Samuels, 1965]. However, one can expect a dependence between the firm's growth and its innovation capacity. The latter is proportional to synergy in interactions among the constituent actors. The actual functional relationship between the firm's size and its innovation and growth capacities needs further investigation in order to complement what has already been found in the literature with respect to the economics of innovation.

Inga Ivanova acknowledges support of the Basic Research Program at the National Research University Higher School of Economics (HSE) and the Russian Academic Excellence Project '5-100'. The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Abramson N. (1963) Information theory and coding, New York: McGraw-Hill.

Analog Devices (2000) Mixed-Signal and DSP Design Techniques (ed. W. Kester), Burlington, MA: Analog Devices, Inc.

Boltzmann L. (1974) The second law of thermodynamics. Populare Schriften, Essay 3, address to a formal meeting of the Imperial Academy of Science, 29 May 1886. Reprinted in Ludwig Boltzmann, Theoretical physics and philosophical problem (translated by S.G. Brush), Boston: Reidel (Original work published in 1886).

Carayannis E.G., Campbell D.F. (2009) 'Mode 3' and 'Quadruple Helix': Toward a 21st Century Fractal Innovation Ecosystem. International Journal of Technology Management, vol. 46, no 3-4, pp. 201-234.

de Groot B., Franses P.H. (2008) Stability through cycles. Technological Forecasting & Social Change, vol. 75, pp. 301-311.

de Groot B., Franses P.H. (2009) Cycles in basic innovations. Technological Forecasting & Social Change, vol. 76, pp. 1021-1025.

de Groot B., Franses P.H. (2012) Common socio-economic cycle periods cycles. Technological Forecasting & Social Change, vol. 79, pp. 56-68.

Dixon R., Shepherd D. (2001) Trends and Cycles in Australian State and Territory Unemployment Rates. The Economic Record, vol. 77, no 238, pp. 252-269.

Dixon R., Shepherd D. (2013) Regional Dimensions of the Australian Business Cycle. Regional Studies, vol. 47, no 2, pp. 264-281.

Etzkowitz H., Leydesdorff L. (2000) The Dynamics of Innovation: From National Systems and 'Mode 2' to a Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government Relations (Introduction to the special "Triple Helix" issue). Research Policy, vol. 29, no 2, pp. 109-123.

Eurostat (2002) Statistical Classification of Economic Activities in the European Community, Rev. 1.1 (NACE Rev. 1.1). Available at: http:// ec.europa.eu/eurostat/ramon/nomenclatures/index.cfm?TargetUrl=LST_CLS_DLD&StrNom=NACE_1_1, accessed 14.04.2018.

Eurostat (2007) NACE Rev. 2 structure and correspondences with NACE Rev 1.1 and ISIC Rev. 4. Available at: http://www.ine.es/daco/ daco42/clasificaciones/cnae09/estructura_en.pdf, accessed 25.08 2014.

Eurostat (2008) Statistical classification of economic activities in the European Community (NACE Rev. 2). Available at: http://ec.europa. eu/eurostat/documents/3859598/5902521/KS-RA-07-015-EN.PDF, accessed 14.04.2018.

Feder J. (1988) Fractals, New York: Plenum Press.

Froyland J. (1992) Fractals. Introduction to Chaos and Coherence (ed. J. Froyland), Bristol: Institute of Physics Publishing, pp. 3-8.

Gibrat R. (1931) Les inégalités économiques, Paris: Sirey.

Hodrick R., Prescott E. (1997) Postwar U.S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 29, no 1, pp. 1-16.

Hurst H.E. (1951) Long term storage capacity of reservoirs. Transactions of the American Society of Civil Engineers, vol. 116, pp. 770-799.

Ivanova I., Leydesdorff L. (2014a) Rotational Symmetry and the Transformation of Innovation Systems in a Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government Relations. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, vol. 86, pp. 143-156.

Ivanova I., Leydesdorff L. (2014b) A simulation model of the Triple Helix of university-industry-government relations and decomposition of redundancy. Scientometrics, vol. 99, no 3, pp. 927-948.

Kondratiev N. (1935) The Long Waves in Economic Life. Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 17, pp. 105-115.

Krippendorff K. (2009a) W. Ross Ashby's information theory: A bit of history, some solutions to problems, and what we face today. International Journal of General Systems, vol. 38, no 2, pp. 189-212.

Krippendorff K. (2009b) Information of interactions in complex systems. International Journal of General Systems, vol. 38, no 6, pp. 669-680.

Krugman P. (1991) Geography and Trade, Leuven: Leuven University Press.

Krugman P. (1993) Lessons of Massachusetts for EMU. Adjustment and Growth in the European Monetary Union (eds. F. Torres, F. Giavazzi), Cambridge (UK): Cambridge University Press, pp. 241-261.

Kuznets S. (1930) Secular Movements in Production and Prices. Their Nature and Their Bearing Upon Cyclical Fluctuations, Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.

Kwon K.S., Park H.W., So M., Leydesdorff L. (2012) Has Globalization Strengthened South Korea's National Research System? National and International Dynamics of the Triple Helix of Scientific Co-authorship Relationships in South Korea. Scientometrics, vol. 90, no 1, pp. 163-176.

Lengyel B., Leydesdorff L. (2011) Regional Innovation Systems in Hungary: The Failing Synergy at the National Level. Regional Studies, vol. 45, no 5, pp. 677-693.

Leydesdorff L. (1995) The Challenge of Scientometrics: The Development, Measurement, and Self-organization of Scientific Communications, Leiden: DSWO Press; Leiden University.

Leydesdorff L. (2010) Redundancy in systems which entertain a model of themselves: Interaction information and the self-organization of anticipation. Entropy, vol. 12, no 1, pp. 63-79.

Leydesdorff L., Dolfsma W., van der Panne G. (2006) Measuring the Knowledge Base of an Economy in terms of Triple-Helix Relations among 'Technology, Organization, and Territory'. Research Policy, vol. 35, no 2, pp. 181-199.

Leydesdorff L., Fritsch M. (2006) Measuring the Knowledge Base of Regional Innovation Systems in Germany in Terms of a Triple Helix Dynamics. Research Policy, vol. 35, no 10, pp. 1538-1553.

Leydesdorff L., Ivanova I. (2014) Mutual Redundancies in Inter-Human Communication Systems: Steps Towards a Calculus of Processing Meaning. Journal of the Association for Information Science and Technology, vol. 65, no 2, pp. 386-399.

Leydesdorff L., Ivanova I. (2016) "Open innovation" and "triple helix" models of innovation: Can synergy in innovation systems be measured? Journal of Open Innovation: Technology, Market, and Complexity, December 2016. Available at: https://link.springer.com/ article/10.1186/s40852-016-0039-7, accessed 16.08.2018.

Leydesdorff L., Park H.W., Lengyel B. (2014) A Routine for Measuring Synergy in University-Industry-Government Relations: Mutual Information as a Triple-Helix and Quadruple-Helix Indicator. Scientometrics, vol. 99, no 1, pp. 27-35.

Leydesdorff L., Perevodchikov E., Uvarov A. (2015) Measuring Triple-Helix Synergy in the Russian Innovation System at Regional, Provincial, and National Levels. Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, vol. 66, no 6, pp. 1229-1238.

Leydesdorff L., Strand 0. (2013) The Swedish System of Innovation: Regional Synergies in a Knowledge-Based Economy. Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, vol. 64, no 9, pp. 1890-1902.

Leydesdorff L., Sun Y. (2009) National and International Dimensions of the Triple Helix in Japan: University-Industry-Government versus International Co-Authorship Relations. Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, vol. 60, no 4, pp. 778-788.

Leydesdorff L., Zhou P. (2014) Measuring the Knowledge-Based Economy of China in Terms of Synergy among Technological, Organizational, and Geographic Attributes of Firms. Scientometrics, vol. 98, no 3, pp. 1703-1719.

Luckraz S. (2013) On innovation cycles in a finite e discrete R&D game. Economic Modelling, vol. 30, pp. 510-513.

McGill W.J. (1954) Multivariate information transmission. Psychometrika, vol. 19, no 2, pp. 97-116.

Megnigbeto E. (2013) Triple Helix of university-industry-government relationships in West Africa. Journal of Scientometric Research, vol. 2, no 3, pp. 214-222.

Megnigbeto E. (2014) Efficiency, unused capacity and transmission power as indicators of the Triple Helix of university-industry-government relationships. Journal of Informetrics, vol. 8, pp. 284-294.

Morgan M. (1992) The History of Econometric Ideas. Journal of Political Economy, vol. 100, no 1, pp. 218-222.

Qian B., Rasheed K. (2004) Hurst exponent and financial market predictability. Paper presented at the IASTED conference on Financial Engineering and Applications, November 8-10, 2004, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA. Available at: https://bit.ly/2nKqx6W, accessed 12.11.2017.

Samuels J.M. (1965) Size and the Growth of Firms. The Review of Economic Studies, vol. 32, no 2, pp. 105-112.

Schumpeter J. (1939) Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical and Statistical Analysis of Capitalist Process, New York: McGraw-Hill.

Shannon C.E. (1948) A mathematical theory of communication. Bell System Technical Journal, vol. 27, no 3-4, pp. 379-423, 623-656.

Statistics Norway (2015) Establishments Data. Available at: https://www.ssb.no/statistikkbanken/selecttable/hovedtabellHjem.asp?Kort NavnWeb=bedrifter&CMSSubjectArea=virksomheter-foretak-og-regnskap&PLanguage=1&checked=true, accessed 18.04.2016.

Strand 0., Ivanova I., Leydesdorff L. (2016) Decomposing the Triple-Helix system into the regional innovation systems of Norway: Firm data and patent networks. Quality & Quantity. DOI 10.1007/s11135-016-0344-z.

Strand 0., Leydesdorff L. (2013) Where is Synergy in the Norwegian Innovation System Indicated? Triple Helix Relations among Technology, Organization, and Geography. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, vol. 80, no 3, pp. 471-484.

Theil H. (1972) Statistical Decomposition Analysis, Amsterdam; London: North-Holland.

Ulanowicz R.E. (1986) Growth and development: Ecosystems phenomenology, New-York: Springer-Verlag.

Ye F., Yu S., Leydesdorff L. (2013) The Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government Relations at the Country Level, and Its Dynamic Evolution under the Pressures of Globalization. Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, vol. 64, no 11, pp. 2317-2325.

Yeung R.W. (2008) Information theory and network coding, New York: Springer.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.