16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
УДК 330.35, 330.4
СТРУКТУРНО-ДИНАМИЧЕСКАЯ ЭКОНОМИЧЕСКАЯ МОДЕЛЬ SDEM-2: ОТ СИСТЕМНО-ДИНАМИЧЕСКИХ РЕШЕНИЙ К МАКСИМИЗАЦИИ ЛИНЕЙНОЙ И ЛОГАРИФМИЧЕСКОЙ ПОЛЕЗНОСТИ
Ковалевский Дмитрий Валерьевич к.ф.-м.н.
Международный центр по окружающей среде и дистанционному зондированию им. Нансена, Санкт-Петербург, Россия
Санкт-Петербургский государственный университет, Санкт-Петербург, Россия
Центр по окружающей среде и дистанционному зондированию им. Нансена, Берген, Норвегия
Структурно-динамическая экономическая модель SDEM-2 является моделью закрытой экономики, растущей в условиях конфликта интересов двух влиятельных агрегированных экономических акторов: предпринимателей и наемных работников. Экономический рост в модели SDEM-2 исследуется в рамках как системно-динамического, так и оптимизационного подходов. В рамках системно-динамического подхода рассматриваются четыре альтернативные управляющие стратегии предпринимателей: «альтруистическая», «умеренный рост выпуска», «здесь и сейчас» и «умеренный рост дивиденда». При оптимизационном подходе с использованием принципа максимума Понтрягина решаются задачи максимизации линейной и логарифмической полезности. Оценивается степень субоптимальности системно-динамических решений
Ключевые слова: ЭКОНОМИЧЕСКИЙ РОСТ, ДИНАМИЧЕСКАЯ СИСТЕМА, ДИНАМИЧЕСКАЯ ОПТИМИЗАЦИЯ
UDC 330.35, 330.4
THE STRUCTURAL DYNAMIC ECONOMIC MODEL SDEM-2: FROM SYSTEM DYNAMIC SOLUTIONS TO LINEAR AND LOGARITHMIC UTILITY MAXIMIZATION
Kovalevsky Dmitry Valerievich Cand.Phys.-Math.Sci.
Nansen International Environmental and Remote Sensing Centre, St. Petersburg, Russia
St. Petersburg State University, St. Petersburg, Russia Nansen Environmental and Remote Sensing Center, Bergen, Norway
The Structural Dynamic Economic Model SDEM-2 is essentially a model of a closed economy growing under conditions of conflict of interests of two powerful aggregate actors: entrepreneurs and wage-earners. We study the economic growth within
SDEM-2 both in system dynamic and optimization model setups. For the system dynamic model setup, four alternative control strategies of entrepreneurs are considered in detail: the “altruistic” control strategy, the “moderate output growth” control strategy, the “here and now” control strategy, and the “moderate dividend growth” control strategy. In the optimization setup the Pontryagin's maximum principle is applied to SDEM-2 to solve the linear and logarithmic utility maximization problems. The degree of sub-optimality of system dynamic solutions is evaluated
Keywords: ECONOMIC GROWTH, DYNAMIC SYSTEM, DYNAMIC OPTIMIZATION
1. Introduction
The Structural Dynamic Economic Model (SDEM) was initially proposed in [2] and later served as a basis for the development of the Multi-Actor Dynamic Integrated Assessment Model (MADIAM) aimed at modeling the dynamics of the coupled climate-socioeconomic system under conditions of global warming [5, 10] - a problem broadly discussed in the economics of climate change [8-9]. In the current paper we provide a brief description of an upgraded model SDEM-2 following Ref. [7] and study
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
the dynamics of a closed economy driven by conflict of interests of two model actors: employers (entrepreneurs) and employees (wage-earners). We treat SDEM-2 both in the system dynamic and the optimization setups.
The paper is organized as follows. Sec. 2 is devoted to a brief description of the model SDEM-2. Sec. 3 describes the system-dynamic model setup. Four alternative control strategies of entrepreneurs are considered in detail: the “altruistic” strategy, the “moderate output growth” strategy, the “here and now” strategy, and the “moderate dividend growth” strategy. In Sec. 4 the dynamic optimization techniques based on the Pontryagin's maximum principle are applied to SDEM-2 to maximize linear and logarithmic utility. Sec. 5 concludes.
2. SDEM-2: model description
In this section we provide a brief overview of the model SDEM-2: detailed derivations of model equations can be found in [6, 7].
SDEM-2 is a model of a closed economy. The population dynamics is exogenous
(the exponential growth of population with a constant rate is assumed), and population (equal to labor force as full employment is assumed) is divided into two social classes: entrepreneurs comprising a constant fraction 0 of population (0 <0 <1) and wage-earners
comprising the remainder (1 _0) of population.
The structure of consumption in the economy is twofold. Wage-earners consume everything they earn (the average wages of a wage-earner are denoted as ). Entrepreneurs do not earn wages - instead, each entrepreneur consumes the “dividend”
The per capita output in the economy depends on per capita physical capital and per capita human capital as two primary production factors. Unlike in standard economic growth models (cf. [1]), these two forms of capital are assumed to be non-substitutable. For the corresponding production function we adopt the Leontief form
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
y = min (ук, ph) (1)
where у , ц are constant factors. An in-depth discussion of the background behind Eq. (1) can be found in [4-6]. In what follows we consider a regime of balanced growth when
У = vh . (2)
The dynamics of the economy is governed by a system of three first-order ordinary differential equations:
k = lk - (A + ^L )k (3)
h = lh -(A +h)h (4)
w = bw (qwtarg - w) (5)
Eqs. (3)-(4) are capital dynamics equations, h and lh being the investments in physical
and human capital, respectively, and Xk and Xh being the depreciation rates of physical and human capital, respectively. Eq. (5) is the wage dynamic equation describing the wage negotiation process between trade unions of wage-earners and entrepreneurs: q is a
parameter reflecting the negotiation power of entrepreneurs (0 < q < 1), Xw is the wage adjustment rate, and Wtarg(t) is a (changing) target -wage rate dependent on the current state of the economy (for the discussion on choice of investments h and lh and calculation of Wtarg(t), see [4-6]).
We now come to non-dimensional variables. First, we introduce an auxiliary constant
(6)
and a non-dimensional parameter
(7)
We note then that if we adopt the method of quantifying the macroeconomic parameters in
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
goods units (as opposed to monetary units), then [к ]=good, [w ]=[d ]=good/year. We introduce new variables with tildes
~ (1-0)u w = w та0 (8)
d =^ d та0 (9)
and a non-dimensional time
*=Kt. (10)
Note that k , w~ and d can be regarded as non-dimensional, if a non-dimensional value is assigned to the unit “good”.
Finally, the problem (3)-(5) can be posed in a non-dimensional form (tildes have been removed from non-dimensional variables)
43 1 £ 1 II (11)
£ 1 II (12)
0 < d < к - w (13)
0 < w0 < k0 (14)
Note that the dimensionality of the dynamic system has been reduced (from 3D to 2D) in view of the additional condition of balanced growth (Eq. (2), see [6-7] for a
discussion). The second inequality in Eq. (13) follows from the additional constraint k - 0 . Eq. (14) is a constraint on initial conditions to make them compatible with the non-zero dividend at the initial time.
To close the model, we should somehow specify the entrepreneurs’ dividend -the control variable of the problem. We will use two alternative model setups: the
system-dynamic model setup and the optimization setup.
In system-dynamic model setup entrepreneurs choose at every instant
according to a certain formalized control strategy, either in the form
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
d (т) = D1{k (t),w(t )) (15)
(as adopted in [5, 10]); or, alternatively, in the form
d(T = D2 (k (т), w(T),d(T)) (16)
(as discussed in detail in [4, 6]).
The optimization model setup implies maximization of entrepreneurs’ utilities. We will use either linear or logarithmic utility function, calculating the utilities in non-dimensional form:
to
Uiin = J d (т)єхр(-Дт)йГ (17)
0 • V '
TO
U*og = J ln[d (т)]єхр(-Дт)йТ (18)
0,
where
Д = 8 (19)
k w
is a non-dimensional discount rate (8 is the dimensional discount rate in Eq. (19)).
3. System-dynamic setup
3.1. The matrix form of dynamic equations
In this section we treat SDEM-2 in system-dynamic model setup. This means that the system (11)-(14) should be supplemented by some control strategy of entrepreneurs formalizing their dividend choice. In what follows we will consider several control strategies of the form given by Eq. (15).
It is convenient to rewrite the dynamic equations (11)-(12) in the matrix form. To do this, we introduce the state vector
(20)
with the initial condition
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
x(0) = x0 = (k0, W0 )T (21)
the matrix
A = (7, ~y^ U -1У (22)
and an auxiliary vector
e =(1, 0)T. (23)
Then Eqs. (11)-(14) can be rewritten in a compact from
0 И II 0s v 4 E- 1 И < II •И (24)
0 < w0 < k0 (25)
0 < d < k - w (26)
In what follows we will consider four different entrepreneurs’ control strategies to close the system (24)-(26): the “altruistic” strategy, the “moderate output growth” strategy, the “here and now” strategy, and the “moderate dividend growth” strategy.
3.2. Control strategies of entrepreneurs
3.2.1. “Altruistic” control strategy
We consider first an (unrealistic) case in which altruistic business strives only to maximize the growth rate of the economy by maximizing the investment, and takes no dividend:
. (27)
The treatment of this case has little economic sense in itself, however, the results of this subsection will be broadly used in the remainder of the paper.
The dynamic equation (24) then takes the homogeneous form
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года with the symbolic solution
х(т) = exp(Ax)x0 . (29)
To examine the dynamic properties of the solution we have to calculate the eigenvalues of the matrix A .
The eigenvalues X± obey the characteristic equation
Da (X) = det(A -XI) = 0 (30)
where 1 is a unit matrix. If q < 1, then the eigenvalues have opposite signs, and the following inequality holds:
-1 <x- < 0 <x+ <j (31)
An example of the numeric solution for “altruistic” control strategy is shown on
Fig. 1.
3.2.2. “Moderate output growth” control strategy
We now assume that entrepreneurs choose their dividend in such a way that the steady growth of per capita physical capital (and consequently of per capita output) at a constant rate a is maintained. Essentially, this means that the output evolves like in the standard AK model [1]. The dynamic system (24)-(26) yields in this case:
k(t) = k0 exp(ax)
w(t) = -qk^exp(aT) + f W0 --^L. 1 exp(-T)
1 + a ( 1 + a)
(in the last equation we have used the notation from Eq. (30)). Since for we
have then in this range of we obtain that when .
Note that the control strategy (34) can be equivalently presented in a form of a simple rule
(32)
(33)
(34)
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
d (т)
1 -°
У У )
к(т) - w(t)
(35)
To sum up, in case of the “moderate output growth” strategy the per capita capital grows exponentially at the rate о (though less rapidly than when the “altruistic” strategy is adopted). The wage rate and the dividend also grow exponentially in the asymptotic limit at the same rate о .
3.2.3. “Here and now” control strategy
Let us consider now the “moderate output growth” strategy (see Sec. 3.2.2) in the limiting case when о = 0 , i.e. when the per capita capital does not grow at all:
к (т) = const = k0 (36)
This situation corresponds to the case in which entrepreneurs decide to choose at every instant the maximum dividend possible for the current state of the economy (the “here and now” strategy):
к = 0, d(T) = к(т) - w(t). (37)
The dynamic system (24)-(26) yields in this case:
w(t) = qk0 + (w0 - qk0)exp(_T) (38)
d(т) =(1 - q)k0 - (w0 - qk0)exp(-T). (39)
Obviously, the “here and now” strategy leads to stagnation: neither the per capita capital nor the output grow, while the wage rate and dividend converge asymptotically to constant values. However, as we will see in Sec. 4.1, in the linear utility maximization model setup and for the case of a sufficiently large discount rate, self-interested entrepreneurs striving to maximize their utility will indeed choose this “here and now” strategy leading to the socially non-optimal situation of stagnation.
The numeric solution for “here and now” control strategy is shown on Fig. 2.
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
3.2.4. “Moderate dividend growth” control strategy
Finally we consider a strategy when entrepreneurs are willing to maintain the growth rate of dividend (not of output, like it was in Sec. 3.2.2) at a constant rate a :
d(t) = d0 exp(ax) (40)
where the initial value of the dividend d° has to be chosen at a maximum level still obeying the model constraints.
Substituting Eq. (40) into Eq. (24), we easily find the solution in the symbolic form
x(t) = exp(AT)(x0 - (A-aI) 1e1yd0 )+ (A-aI) 1e1yd0 exp(ax)
(41)
Clearly, the bigger the initial value of the dividend d0 the better for entrepreneurs
However, the solution should obey the proper constraints. It can be shown that entrepreneurs can choose d0 in Eq. (40) according to the formula
d0 = min
Я+ -a
у
k0-----r- w0
У-Я-
, k0 - w0
(42)
У
We will see below that in the case of logarithmic utility maximization (Sec. 4.2) the exponential growth of dividend (i.e. the “moderate dividend growth” control strategy) proves to be the optimal entrepreneurs’ choice.
4. Optimization setup
4.1. Linear utility maximization
Now we come to the optimization model setup for SDEM-2. As discussed in Sec. 2, the dynamic equations and constraints should be supplemented in this case by the utility maximization condition. In this subsection we consider the dynamic system (24)-(26) supplemented by the linear utility maximization condition (20):
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
0 < w0 < k0 (44)
0 < d < k - w (45)
TO maxyim = max J d (T)exp(-AT)dx 0 (46)
This problem can be solved by applying the Pontryagin's maximum principle in its general form [3] allowing to take into account the constraints on control variables depending on state variables (such a constraint appears in the second inequality in Eq. (45)).
For the linear utility maximization problem under consideration the corresponding Hamiltonian is linear in d , therefore it is evident that the system always evolves along one of the boundaries of the phase space:
either d = 0 or d = k - w , (47)
with possible occasional instant discontinuous “switches” from one boundary to the other (the relay control). Therefore we immediately choose the “here and now” entrepreneurs’ control strategy when d(t) = k(t) - w(x) as a candidate for the optimal solution. But would not the entrepreneurs be willing to stick at some time spans to the “altruistic” control strategy (d(x) = 0) and to sacrifice their dividend for a while, allowing the economy to grow as fast as it can, and then switching to the “here-and-now” strategy to enjoy the extensive consumption with more attractive initial conditions?
An analysis shows that if A > , then the “here and now” control strategy of
entrepreneurs (Sec. 3.2.3) is the optimal strategy when the linear utility (46) is maximized.
In the opposite case the linear utility (46) can be made arbitrarily high by
combining the “altruistic” and “here and now” control strategies.
A constructive example of a set of control strategies providing the arbitrarily high
level of linear utility when is as follows: initially to adopt the “altruistic” control
strategy ( , ) and then to switch to “here-and-now” strategy ( ,
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
т>%1). It can be shown that
U*m (x1) ^ +<ю when X1 ^ +* .
Explicitly, the maximum value of utility (46) when
Д > x+
and entrepreneurs adopt
the "here-and-now" (HN) strategy, can be calculated from a simple formula
иlin - f T x U HN* _'HNa0
(48)
where
*HN
^ 1 - q + Д
КД (Д +1) ’
1
Д+1
J
T
(49)
and x0 is the initial condition.
It is instructive to calculate the linear utilities for three other control strategies considered in Sec. 3.2 and to evaluate the degree of “sub-optimality” of these control strategies. We omit the derivations and provide here only the final results.
(i) The “altruistic” control strategy (A):
UA* - o; (50)
(ii) The “moderate output growth” control strategy (MOG):
иlin - fT x
U MOG* - 'MOGa0
(51)
where
f
fMOG -
V
Da (a) + q________L_
y(1 + a) 1 + a Д +1’
1
Д +1
T
(52)
(iii) The “moderate dividend growth” control strategy (MDG):
(53)
where, depending on the relation between and , either
(54)
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
or
1
MDG
A-а
•(1, - 1)T
(55)
The degree of sub-optimality ^ of г -th control strategy from (i)-(iii) can then be evaluated according to the formula
Ц, = 1-
U*m
иlm
U HN*
(56)
4.2. Logarithmic utility maximization
Finally we consider the logarithmic utility maximization problem. The system of equations (43)-(45) should be supplemented now by the logarithmic utility maximization condition (23):
0 И II 0s v 1 и < II •и (57)
0 < w0 < k0 (58)
0 < d < k - w (59)
TO maxU*log = max Jln[d(T)]exp(-AT)dx 0. (60)
We write down the Hamiltonian H = ln[d]exp(-Ax) + 9T(Ax -yexd) (61)
where is a vector of shadow variables. The maximization of in
provides the condition
(62)
while the dynamic system for shadow variables takes the explicit form
. (63)
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
It is easy to check that if the eigenvalues of the matrix A are equal to A+, , and
A-< 0<x+, then the eigenvalues of the matrix (-AT) are equal to (-A+), (-A-), and
-A+ < o<-x_ . Therefore the general solution of the homogeneous system (63) is given by a formula
ф(т) = ф+ exp(-A+x) + ф- exp(-A_x) (64)
where ф+, ф- are eigenvectors of the matrix (- AT ).
The transversality condition (ф(х) ^ 0 when x ^ +да) forces us to exclude the second (growing) term from the r.h.s. of Eq. (64). Thus,
ф(х) = ф+ exp(-A+T) (65)
and, particularly,
Vk(x) = Vk0 exp(-A+x) . (66)
By substituting Eq. (66) into Eq. (62) we get a candidate for the optimal solution in
the form of the “moderate dividend growth” control strategy with a = A+ - A ;
d(x) = d0 exp((A+ - A)x ) . (67)
Restricting ourselves to the practically interesting case of growing, not decaying,
economy, we impose the constraint A < A+. Then we can make use of the results of Sec. 3.2.4 to write down the optimal solution. Having calculated in such a way the initial
value d(0, we are then able to calculate the utility (60), the final result being
(68)
In the following we will restrict ourselves to the case into Eq. (42) we get
. By substituting
(69)
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
(we have used here the identity 7 1 + x+).
It can be shown that for w° < qk° the first option in Eq. (69) is always smaller than the second one, so
d0 -
A
7
k0
7
1 + Я+
w0
(70)
Therefore we come to the optimal strategy of the form
d (t) = —
7
k0
7
1 + Л+
-w0
exi
p((A+-A>)
(71)
It can be easily shown that in case of optimal control strategy the identity (70) holds not only for the initial time, but also for every time:
d (t)
— k(t)- —7— w(t) 7 L 1 +я+
(72)
So the entrepreneurs actually have to follow a very simple rule (72) when choosing the value of the dividend.
The sub-optimality of other control strategies can be evaluated in this case by applying a formula analogous to Eq. (56).
5. Conclusions
The model SDEM-2 considered in this paper proved to be quite unique in that it overcomes in many respects the watershed between system-dynamic macroeconomic models and optimization models (the latter being more deeply implanted in neoclassical economic growth theory [1]). Indeed, as is shown in Sec. 4, two of the four quite natural and straightforward control strategies of entrepreneurs - the “here and now” control strategy (Sec. 3.2.3) and the “moderate dividend growth” control strategy (Sec. 3.2.4) -provide at the same time the optimal solutions in case of linear and logarithmic utility maximization problems, respectively. From purely mathematical viewpoint, one of the
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
reasons for this “coincidence” is in adoption of the Leontief production function (Eq. (1)) which is essentially linear in physical (and human) capital in case of balanced growth (Eq. (2)) on which the current paper is focused.
We are planning to use the results obtained in this paper when developing a stylized Integrated Assessment model based on system-dynamic version of SDEM-2 to evaluate the efficiency of potential imposition of global carbon price as climate mitigation policy [9-10].
Acknowledgements
The author would like to thank Prof. Klaus Hasselmann for helpful comments. This study was supported by the Nansen Scientific Society (Bergen, Norway, Project No. 5/2011), and by the Russian Foundation for Basic Research (Projects No. 10-06-00369 and 12-06-00381).
References
1. Barro R.J., Sala-i-Martin X. Economic Growth. McGraw-Hill, 1995.
2. Barth V. Integrated assessment of climate change using structural dynamic models. Ph.D. Thesis. Max-Planck-Institut fur Meteorologie, Hamburg, 2003. URL: http://www.mpimet.mpg.de/fileadmin/publikationen/Ex91.pdf (accessed 30.10.2012).
3. Boltyansky V.G. Mathematical Methods of Optimal Control. Moscow: Nauka, 1969. 408 p. [Болтянский В.Г. Математические методы оптимального управления. М.: Наука, 1969. 408 с.]
4. Hasselmann K. Simulating human behavior in macroeconomic models applied to climate change. European Climate Forum. Working Paper 3/2009. ISBN: 978-3-941663-03-9. URL: http://www.globalclimateforum.org/fileadmin/ecf-documents/publications/ecf-working-papers/hasselman
n__simultating-human-behavior-in-macroeconomic-models-applied-to-climate-change.pdf (accessed
30.10.2012).
5. Hasselmann K., Kovalevsky D.V. Simulating animal spirits in actor-based environmental models // Environmental Modelling and Software. 2012. Vol. 44. P. 10-24.
6. Kovalevsky D.V. Balanced growth in the Structural Dynamic Economic Model SDEM-2 // Discontinuity, Nonlinearity, and Complexity. 2014. Vol. 3, Iss. 3. P. 237-253.
7. Kovalevsky D.V. Optimal growth paths under different utility specifications, with application to the Structural Dynamic Economic Model SDEM-2 // St. Petersburg Polytechnical University Journal. Economics [Научно-технические ведомости СПбГПУ. Серия: Экономические науки.] - 2012. No. 6(161). P. 188-192.
8. Matveenko V.D. Stimulating mechanisms in ecologically motivated regulation: will ecological
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
policies in transition and developing countries become efficient? // Journal of the New Economic Association. 2010. No. 8. P. 10-34. [Русская версия: Матвеенко В.Д. Стимулирующие механизмы в экологически мотивированном регулировании: станут ли эффективными экологические политики в переходных и развивающихся экономиках? // Журнал Новой экономической ассоциации. 2010. № 8. C. 10-34.]
9. Stern N. The Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge, 2006. 712 p.
10. Weber M., Barth V., Hasselmann K. A multi-actor dynamic integrated assessment model (MADIAM) of induced technological change and sustainable economic growth // Ecological Economics.
2005. Vol. 54. P. 306-327.
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf
16
Научный журнал КубГАУ, №104(10), 2014 года
FIGURES
Figure 1: The
dynamics of non-dimensional capital k , wages
strategy.
w and dividend d for “altruistic” control
0,0 J
0 20 40 60 80 100
Time [years]
Figure 2: The dynamics of non-dimensional capital , wages
control strategy.
and dividend for “here and now”
http://ej.kubagro.ru/2014/10/pdf/011.pdf