Научная статья на тему 'Solving Fiscal Problems through Monetary Policy Mechanisms: Case of Armenia'

Solving Fiscal Problems through Monetary Policy Mechanisms: Case of Armenia Текст научной статьи по специальности «Экономика и бизнес»

CC BY
145
32
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
Журнал
Финансы: теория и практика
Scopus
ВАК
RSCI
Область наук
Ключевые слова
monetary regulation / monetary policy / inflation / fiscal policy / fiscal dominance / монетарное регулирование / валютная политика / инфляция / налогово-бюджетная политика / фискальное доминирование

Аннотация научной статьи по экономике и бизнесу, автор научной работы — Mariam A. Voskanyan, Lilit V. Paronyan

The problem of fiscal dominance tends to be most pronounced in emerging markets. The research subject is the monetary policy of the Central Bank of the Republic of Armenia and its participation in solving fiscal problems. The aim of the article is to analyze and assess fiscal dominance in the macroeconomic regulation of Armenia. The methodological basis of the study is a review of theoretical and practical models of fiscal dominance known in the scientific literature, as well as applying the most optimal models to the Armenian economy. The authors conclude that the tasks of fiscal policy are the priority of macroeconomic management, and monetary policy aims to solve fiscal problems

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.

Решение фискальных проблем посредством механизмов денежно-кредитной политики: на примере Армении

Проблема фискального доминирования, как правило, наиболее ярко проявляется в странах с развивающимися рынками. Предметом исследования является монетарная политика Центрального банка Республики Армения с точки зрения ее участия в решении налогово-бюджетных задач. Цель исследования — анализ и оценка фискального доминирования в макроэкономическом регулировании Армении. Методологической базой исследования стал обзор теоретических и практических моделей фискального доминирования, известных в научной литературе, а также апробация наиболее оптимальных из них на примере экономики Армении. В результате исследования сделан вывод, что в приоритете макроэкономического регулирования стоят задачи налогово-бюджетной политики, и монетарная политика направлена на решение фискальных проблем.

Текст научной работы на тему «Solving Fiscal Problems through Monetary Policy Mechanisms: Case of Armenia»

ORIGINAL PAPER

DOI: 10.26794/2587-5671-2020-24-6-61-81 JEL E52, E62, 023

(CO ]

Solving Fiscal Problems through Monetary Policy Mechanisms: Case of Armenia

M. A. Voskanyana, L.V. Paronyanb

Russian-Armenian University, Yerevan, Armenia a https://orcid.org/0000-0002-5417-6648; b https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5351-8039

ABSTRACT

The problem of fiscal dominance tends to be most pronounced in emerging markets. The research subject is the monetary policy of the Central Bank of the Republic of Armenia and its participation in solving fiscal problems. The aim of the article is to analyze and assess fiscal dominance in the macroeconomic regulation of Armenia. The methodological basis of the study is a review of theoretical and practical models of fiscal dominance known in the scientific literature, as well as applying the most optimal models to the Armenian economy. The authors conclude that the tasks of fiscal policy are the priority of macroeconomic management, and monetary policy aims to solve fiscal problems.

Keywords: monetary regulation; monetary policy; inflation; fiscal policy; fiscal dominance

For citation: Voskanyan M.A., Paronyan L. V. Solving fiscal problems through monetary policy mechanisms: Case of Armenia. Finance: Theory and Practice. 2020;24(6):61-81. DOI: 10.26794/2587-5671-2020-24-6-61-81

ОРИГИНАЛЬНАЯ СТАТЬЯ

Решение фискальных проблем посредством механизмов денежно-кредитной политики: на примере Армении

М.А. Восканян3, Л. В. Паронянь

Российско-армянский университет, Ереван, Армения а https://orcid.org/0000-0002-5417-6648; ь https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5351-8039

BY 4.0

АННОТАЦИЯ

Проблема фискального доминирования, как правило, наиболее ярко проявляется в странах с развивающимися рынками. Предметом исследования является монетарная политика Центрального банка Республики Армения с точки зрения ее участия в решении налогово-бюджетных задач. Цель исследования - анализ и оценка фискального доминирования в макроэкономическом регулировании Армении. Методологической базой исследования стал обзор теоретических и практических моделей фискального доминирования, известных в научной литературе, а также апробация наиболее оптимальных из них на примере экономики Армении. В результате исследования сделан вывод, что в приоритете макроэкономического регулирования стоят задачи налогово-бюджетной политики, и монетарная политика направлена на решение фискальных проблем. Ключевые слова: монетарное регулирование; валютная политика; инфляция; налогово-бюджетная политика; фискальное доминирование

Для цитирования: Восканян М.А., Паронян Л. В. Решение фискальных проблем посредством механизмов денежно-кредитной политики: на примере Армении. Финансы: теория и практика. 2020;24(6):61-81. DOI: 10.26794/25875671-2020-24-6-61-81

© Voskanyan М.А, Paronyan L.V., 2020

INTRODUCTION

The strategic goal of macroeconomic regulation is to achieve sustainable economic growth rate in terms of stable prices and national currency, low unemployment together with free capital flow. Thus, all of the above indicators characterizing macroeconomic stability are closely interrelated.

As a rule, the choice of priorities for macroeconomic regulation in the economy is adaptive. In particular, this approach is inherent in developing countries or countries with economies in transition, since the conditions of uncertainty and lack of macroeconomic stability are often chronic. At the same time, this approach does not provide a strategic direction for the development of the economy and largely hinders the achievement of sustainable economic growth.

A key challenge faced by developing societies is the high public debt and inability to pay off debt in the near future, which is very closely related to slow economic growth. In such conditions, macroeconomic policy tends to solve the fiscal problems associated with public debt and high public deficit by all possible means, including monetary mechanisms. For this reason, developing countries choose to opt for fiscal dominance in their macroeconomic policies. Armenia is a good example.

LITERATURE REVIEW: THEORETICAL PREMISES OF FISCAL DOMINANCE IN MACROECONOMIC POLICIES

Fiscal dominance takes place in the economy when all macroeconomic decisions are based on the priorities of fiscal policy. This means that with a conflict of interest between monetary and fiscal policies, the choice is made in favor of fiscal problems, and monetary instruments are inevitable to solve problems with public debt and budget deficits. One of the most famous theories of fiscal dominance in macroeconomic regulation is "The Fiscal Theory of the Price Level", first described by E. Leiper (1991), K. Sims (1994), M. Woodford (1994, 1995) [1-4].

The author of earlier studies M. Bassetto (2008) [5] prioritizes the role of public debt and fiscal policy in the pricing process in the economy, while monetary policy plays an indirect role. The author relied on data from the crisis and post-crisis periods, which clearly proved that monetary mechanisms are overshadowed by economic shocks. However, ten years later, M. Bassetto and W. Cui in their work "The Fiscal Theory of the Price Level in a World of Low Interest Rates" (2017) [6] showed that the fiscal theory of the price level is not a good balancing tool in a context when interest rates are not outstripping long-term growth. Taylor's equation

(1993) [7] also supports this idea (Equation 1), based on the sensitivity of the interest rate level to changes in the price level and to the difference between real and potential GDP.

Equation 1

R = P + 0.5(7 - Y*)/Y* + 0.5(P - 0.02) + 0.02,

where R is the nominal interest rate, P is the prior period inflation, Y is the real GDP, Y* is the potential GDP, and 0.02 is the most optimal inflation target according to Taylor — 2%.

The work by W. H. Buiter (2002) [8] is one of the critics of FTPL. As a counterargument, it suggests the thesis that this approach carries many contradictions and violations of the laws of economic theories, in particular, in achieving a balance only in the face of budget restrictions.

Many researchers attempted to build mathematical and econometric models to reveal fiscal dominance. In particular, the study by H. Bohn (1998) [9] (Equation 2):

Equation 2

PBt = a+b * Dt_ + e,,

where PBt is the primary balance scaled by GDP for the current period, Dt _1 is the public debt scaled by GDP of the previous period, a and b are the model parameters, and et is the errors.

This equation is based on the thesis that if the coefficient b is significant and positive, it indicates monetary dominance. However, FTPL proponents, who argued that positive rating b could also indicate fiscal dominance in certain circumstances, as it reflects government fiscal sustainability, criticized this theory.

Many studies measured fiscal dominance in sample countries. For example, Carlos de Resende (2007) [10] tried to estimate fiscal dominance and monetary independence by examining OECD countries as well as a group of developing countries that are part of the IMF group. The research by the author showed that fiscal dominance is inherent in many developing countries, while in developed countries monetary authorities are highly independent. The author singles out the institutional environment and its development as a reason for such dynamics.

From the experience of several European developing economies, I. Milenkovich (2018) [11] conducted an empirical analysis using the econometric VAR model. He found that, first, a prerequisite for inflationary expectations in these countries is fiscal management (which might be a valid argument for applying FTPL). Second, in these countries fiscal policy, rather than

monetary policy, prevails. Based on the analysis of the quarterly data of the primary balance sheet and the consolidated gross public debt of five developing countries in Europe (Hungary, Romania, Bulgaria, Serbia and Macedonia), the author built two regression models (Equation 3) that describe fiscal or monetary dominance in the economy.

Equation 3

k+dmax k+dmax = - j + IPY - j+s,,

j=1 j=i

k+dmax k+dmax

Y = ZYj*' - j+ZW- j+ n'

j=i j=i

where Xt is the government budget deficit, Yt is the consolidated gross debt, a j ,p j, y jand 5 j are model parameters, k is the optimal number of lags in the initial VAR model, dmax is the maximum sequence integration in the system, and st and nt are the errors of the first and second regressions respectively.

The key finding of the study was that the causal relationship between government debt and budget deficits reduces the ability of monetary authorities to effectively determine policies to achieve their own goals, and as a result, they lose autonomy in regulating the economy.

K. Sanusi and A. Akinlo (2015) [12] proposed their own approach to defining fiscal dominance in macro-economic policy. Their research refers to the work by M. Fratianni and F. Spinelli (2001) [13], based on the assumption that the causal relationship between the budget deficit and the increase in the monetary base in the economy is direct. The focus of the research by K. Sanusi and A. Akinlo was to identify the fiscal dominance in Nigeria. The VAR model is as follows (Equation 4):

Equation 4

Y xt ]=K a20 ] + [«11 ai2 a21 a22 ] [Y-i X-i ] + [eytext],

where Yt is the budget deficit of the current period, Xt is the growth of money base, the first term and the first part of the second term are parameters of the regression model, and the last term is errors.

The study failed to prove the existence of fiscal dominance in Nigeria, because other mechanisms of fiscal dominance were used there.

The link between government spending and inflation is presented in the book by H. Khan, M. Marimuthu and F.-W. Lai (2020) [14]. It describes several stages of financing the budget deficit. Their research is based

on the formula linking inflation and budget deficit described in the study by K. Ali and M. Khalid [15]. The relationship between inflation and budget deficits is as follows (Equation 5):

Equation 5

CPIt = a0 + p^ + №DPt + P3M2t +

where CPI is the Consumer Price Index, FD is the Fiscal Deficit, GDP is the Gross Domestic Product, M2 is the money supply.

Since the model does consider the methods of financing the government deficit, the authors modified it as follows (Equation 6):

Equation 6

CPIt = «0 + PDB + P^t + P/S + PM2 + PsGDPt + %

where DB is domestic borrowings, EB is external borrowings.

The third phase reveals the categories of internal and external borrowings (Equation 7):

Equation 7

CPIt = «o + PCBBt + P2BIB + P4M2t + P5GDPt + P6PSt + P7MLTt + P8STXt + et,

where CBB is Central Bank borrowings, BIB is bank borrowings, PS is political instability, MLT is medium and long term borrowings, STL is short term borrowings.

In their work, M. Mehrara, M. B. Soufiani and S. Rezael (2016) [16] consider government spending within expansionary and restrictive monetary regimes. They find that in the case of the former, an increase in government spending is not inflationary and may even contribute to economic development, but it is inflationary in the latter. Both may cause price changes, but the first regime can minimize the negative effects of inflationary pressures. The authors' findings are not entirely consistent with FTPL, as the latter suggests the impact of inflationary pressures on government spending. However, the opposite is also true, when prices are kept at a certain level in order to maintain optimal costs from the government budget.

We believe that this approach can be identified through the model described in the work by H. Khan, M. Marimuta and F.-W. Lai (2020) [14]. First, the following simple econometric model is as follows (Equation 8):

Equation 8 CPIt = a0 + efDt + + P3M2t +

The equation describes the direct relationship between inflation and the state budget deficit of the country without considering the internal and external sources of financing the budget deficit. The model with these parameters is as follows (Equation 9):

Equation 9

CPIt = a0 + exCBBt + e£IBt + VAM2t + V5GDPt + P6PSt + e7MLTt + + s,

The authors concluded that in the short term, government borrowing will not have a negative impact on the inflationary background in the economy, while in the long term, this impact will be significant.

Thus, the literature suggests three key mechanisms of fiscal dominance.

The first mechanism is to solve the problem of the budget deficit by increasing the money supply, contrary to the principles of monetary regulation. Thus, fiscal policy dominates macroeconomic management.

The second mechanism is based on the close relationship between domestic prices and government spending. In the case of fiscal dominance, the government prefers to keep prices at a certain level to reduce budget spending. At the same time, the target may damage economic growth. This approach is most pronounced in developing countries prone to inflation, where prices are chosen as the best target for the government budget, rather than for sustainable economic growth.

The third mechanism is monetary regulation and its close link to the external debt. If the external liabilities cannot be met in the short term, countries often use monetary policy to maintain constant external debt. Fiscal dominance is also pronounced here.

In the real world, countries are not limited to one of the above mechanisms for solving fiscal problems through monetary policy mechanisms, but tend to use all these mechanisms of fiscal dominance. In this regard, we will further consider all three mechanisms of fiscal dominance using the case of the Armenian economy.

FISCAL DOMINANCE: CASE OF ARMENIA

In this study, we have assessed fiscal dominance in the macroeconomic regulation of Armenia, using the above monetary mechanisms for solving fiscal problems. The considered cases are as follows.

Fiscal dominance: monetizing government deficits

Budget deficits are common in most developing countries. Moreover, countries often use monetary instruments to deal with the default on government deficits. Monetizing the government deficit actually indicates the priority of fiscal policy in macroeco-nomic management. The deficit balance (Fig. 1) characterizes the state budget of the Republic of Armenia. Chronic state budget deficits have been observed over the past thirty years.

Since the monetization of the state deficit depends more on the structure and growth of the money supply, the structure of the money supply and the monetary base in Armenia was considered as indicators of the money supply.

Figure 2 shows that the growth of money supply over the last 10 year has been driven largely by the growth of term and foreign currency deposits. At the same time, the growth of cash turnover is almost non-existent, due to the decline of consumption in the economy, as well as the decrease in household income. There was a slight increase in demand deposits. Foreign currency deposits account for a large share in the overall structure of the money supply, which reflects the high dollarization of the country's money supply.

The monetary base structure also indicates no significant growth in the money supply of the economy. The growth of the monetary base is due to the growth of correspondent accounts in national and foreign currency in the banking system.

The next step is to define a model that would determine the monetization of the state budget deficit in the Armenian economy. The model is as follows.

• Methodology: Characteristics of the government deficit monetization model

In the case of fiscal dominance, the government can use mechanisms for monetizing the state budget deficit, which will definitely affect the independence of the monetary authorities in macroeconomic management.

We went for the model by M. Fratianni and F. Spinel-li [13] to describe the existence of fiscal dominance by monetizing the state budget deficit. The model is a step-by-step determination of fiscal dominance in the country's macroeconomic management.

First, it is necessary to assess the quantitative impact of the monetary component of the state budget. We start the calculations with the methodology for accounting for money supply growth.

To solve this problem, the authors initially use the money-supply formula and its derivatives (Equation 10):

-2000

Fig. 1. Government spending, revenue and deficit/surplus, quarterly, in billion AMD

Source: database of the National Statistical Service of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.armstat.am (accessed on 12.10.2020).

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 20192020

Fig. 2. Monthly money supply, billion AMD

Source: database of the Central Bank of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.cba.am (accessed on 12.10.2020).

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 20192020

Fig. 3. Monthly money base, billion AMD

Source: database of the Central Bank of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.cba.am (accessed on 12.10.2020).

Equation 10 where Mt is the money supply, mt is the money multiplier, MBt is the money base, rrt is the reserve ration, ret — deposit rate, BRt is the reserve requirement, BЕt is the excess reserves, BRt is the cash, Dt is the deposits.

These formulas do not describe the growth of monetary base, so Equation (10) was transformed into the following: (Equation 11):

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

Mt = mtMBt, mt = (1 + k)/(k + rrt + re), K = BPD

rrt = BR/D, ret = BE/D,,

Equation 11

ln mt — ln mtl = c(k) + c(rr) + c(re) + c(com1), c(k) = ln(1 + k) —- ln(1 + kj — ln(kt + rrul + rej + + ln(kM + rrtl + re—1), c(rr) = -ln(kM + rrt + retA) + ln(kt_j + rrM + reM), c(re) = -ln(ktl + rrtl + re—) + ln(kM + rrM + reM), c(com1) = lnmt — lnmt—1 — [c(k) + c(rr) + c(re)].

Then, it was transformed into Equation 12:

Equation 12

lnMBt — lnMBt—1 = c(MBTR) + c(MBOT) + c(BF) + + c(com2),

c(MBTR) = ln(MBTRt + MBOT—1 + BFt ) — ln(MBTRt 1 +

+ MBOTtl + BFJ, c(MBOT) = ln(MBTRt j + MBOTt + BFt j) — ln(MBTRt 1 + + MBOTtl + BFJ, c(BF) = ln(MBTRt j + MBOTt j + BF) — ln(MBTRt 1 +

+ MBOTtl + BFJ, c(com2) = lnMBt — lnMBt 1 — [c(MBTR) + c(MBOT) + + c(BF)],

where MBTR is the government bonds, MBOT is the non-governmental bonds, BF is the foreign component of securities, com1 an indicator that integrates the determinants of multiples, and com2 is an indicator that integrates the determinants of the monetary base.

The first set of equations passed to the second one using Equation 13:

Equation 13

MB = MBTR + MBOT + BF.

With these equations, the authors identified the contribution of each indicator into the monetary growth.

Then goes the analysis of the impact of the budget deficit on the growth of the earlier component of the monetary base. It helps assess how the deficit has been solved through the monetization of the economy and to identify the elements of fiscal dominance. To this end, the authors analyzed the impact of the budget on the state component of the money supply. They suggested that a positive relationship between indicators could be a prerequisite for fiscal dominance, while the absence of this relationship indicates that it does not exist. The following type of regression analysis was used:

Equation 14

DMBTR = a0 + a1DMBTRt_1 +...+ aDMBTRt_n + b0DEFYt +... + bDEFYtn + cDEFY(CRE) + "dDEFY(MAAS) + u,

where DMBTR = (MBTRt - MBTRt l)/Yt l, DEFY=DEF/ Yt_v Y is the net national income, CRE is the dummy variable (1 in the period 1981-1992, 0 in other cases), MAAS is the dummy variable (1 in the period 19931997, 0 in other cases).1

Finally, the authors assessed the relationship between the general monetary base growth and the budget deficit. It makes it possible to determine whether fiscal policy should be given priority in the country's macroeconomic management.

To this end, the authors tested the relationship between the relative change in the total monetary base and the budget deficit by regression analysis of the type in Equation (15). The model is as follows:

Equation 15

DMB = e0 + f1DMB-1 +...+fnDMB-n + gfiEFY +... + g„DEFYtn + hDEFY (CRE) + "nDEFY(MAAS) + qDY+

+ sidifí + vCAB + z riiff + ^

where DMB = (MBt - MBt-1)/Yt-1, idiffis the difference between the return on assets and the cost of borrowing from the Central Bank, rdiff is the difference between Italian and foreign interest rates, e is the errors.

The researchers conclude that the monetization of the budget deficit decreases over time and may even be reversible, which indicates that solving fiscal problems by monetizing the state budget leads to an excessive increase in the money supply in the economy and, as a consequence, to additional inflationary pressure.

• Testing the model of budget deficit monetization in the economy of Armenia

The model described above is adapted to the specifics of the Armenian economy, considering the key features and factors between the budget deficit and the money supply. To build the model of the Armenian economy, we used the monetary base, the volume of government securities on the market and the state budget deficit (from the first quarter of 2008 to the fourth quarter of 2019). The percentage of foreign participation in the securities market was excluded from the indicators in the original model, since the capitalization of the stock market in Armenia is about 2% of GDP and is not significant in terms of money supply.

The data were cleared of seasonality, logarized, and the differences between the current and previous values were calculated. The data distribution was normalized. The data were tested for normality using the Shapiro-Wilk and Shapiro-Francia tests. The distribution of all

1 CRE and MAAS are specific variables for the Italian economy.

Table 1

VAR analysis of the impact of changes in the state component of the monetary base

and the monetary base

Coef. Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf* I nterval]

mb mb

LI, .1333205 .1417833 0 94 0.347 -.1445696 .4112107

govtb

LI. -.0115482 .0057165 -2 02 0.043 -.0227522 -.0003441

_cons .0200455 . 0062981 3 18 0.001 .0077014 .0323896

govtb inb

LI. -.3932807 2.717911 -0 14 0.885 -5.7202 89 4.933727

govtb

LI . -.6759048 .1095816 -6 17 0.000 - .8906808 -.4611287

cons .1597744 .1207317 1 32 0.186 -.0768553 .3964042

Note: mb is the money base, govtb is the government securities. Source: calculated by the authors.

data is normal (Appendix, Table 1), and the time series is stationary (Appendix, Table 2).

We built a VAR model (Table 1) to find the correlation between the growth of the monetary base and the growth of government securities. Before that, we tested its order criterion and chose the first order (Appendix, Table 3). There is a one lag correlation between government securities, meaning that an increase in government securities over one time period affects the monetary base and, therefore, the amount of money in circulation in Armenia.

The model was tested using the Granger causality test, where the null hypothesis is that a lagging variable (in this case, one lag) does not cause the dependent variable to change. Table 2 presents the test result. The test result showed that the null hypothesis is accepted with a probability of 4.3% for the model with the monetary base as the dependent variable. This means that the null hypothesis is denied. In other words, changes in the monetary base are inversely affected by changes in the number of government securities.

The next step was to assess the impact of changes in the state budget deficit on changes in the volume of government securities. We calculated the order criterion for the model and chose lag-4 (Appendix, Table 4). We built the VAR model with these three variables. Table 3 presents the result.

Table 3 shows that the changes in government deficits have no impact on the volume of government securities. The Granger causality test also proves this point (Table 4).

The last step was to identify the link between the monetary base and state budget deficit. For this pur-

Table 2

Granger causality test of the state component of the monetary base and monetary base

Granger causality Wald te&ti

Equation Excluded chi2 df Prob > cbi2

mb govtb 4.081 1 0 043

mb ALL 4.081 1 0 043

govtb mb .02094 1 0 685

govtb ALL .02094 1 0 885

Source: calculated by the authors.

Table 3

VAR analysis of state budget deficit and government securities

Coef. Std. Ere. z P>l zl |95% Conf. Interval]

govtb

govtb

LI. -.6L40958 .1523062 -4 03 0 000 -.9126144 -.3155773

L2 ■ .1673323 .1786786 O 94 0 34 9 -.1828713 .5175358

L.3. .0167982 .178 9218 0 09 0 925 -.333682 .3674785

L4 . -.1394247 .1520983 -0 92 0 359 -.4375319 .1586824

def

LI. -.2248432 .4535043 -O 50 0 620 -1.113695 .6640088

L2. -.5644248 .4 62707 6 -1 22 0 223 -1.471315 .3424654

L3. -.5454681 .4871452 -1 12 0 263 -1.500255 .4093189

L4 . -.3900071 .4814185 -0 81 0 4 IB: -1.33357 .5535558

_cons .1408481 .1080592 1 30 0 192 -.070944 .352 64 02

def

govtb

LI. -.0323687 .0446701 -0 72 0 4 69 -.1199205 .0551831

L2 . -.0251058 .0524042 -0 48 0 632 -.1278162 .077604 6

l3. .0316681 .0524756 0 60 0 54 S -.0711621 .1345183

L4 . -.0033308 .0446086 -0 07 0 940 -.0907 62 .0841003

def

LI. -.4 208134 .1330072 -3 16 0 002 -.6815028 -.160124

L2 . -.4 593744 .1357064 -3 39 0 001 -.7253541 -.1933946

L3. -.4133584 .1426737 -2 89 0 004 -.6933657 -.1333311

L4 . .5436343 .1411941 3 85 0 000 .2660989 .8203697

CO CIS .00 655 98 .0316924 0 21 0 836 -.0555562 .0686759

Note: govtb is the government securities, def is the budget deficit. Source: calculated by the authors.

pose, the order of the VAR model (Appendix, Table 5) was analyzed and the fourth order was chosen. Table 5 presents the result. The relationship between the budget deficit and the monetary base was not found at the 5% significance level. However, at the 10% significance level, the budget deficit has a positive effect on the monetary base. This means that if the deficit grows in the next quarter, the monetary base will increase, and hence the money supply.

Granger causality test showed no connection between monetary base and deficit (Table 66).

The study also examined the effect of external and internal shocks on individual regressions and the responses to these impulses of the remaining regressions by the impulse response function (Fig. 4) and the orthogonal impulse response function (Fig. 5). Since the shocks identified by the impulse response function are intrinsic, it can be argued that these shocks are due to a sharp increase or decrease in the variable itself, which may be caused by unforeseen circumstances (the COVID-19 pandemic and the associated sharp increase in government spending). In this case, impulses for change will be based on the size of the government expenditure variable, and the response will be reflected on other variables.

The orthogonalized impulse-response function shows the external shock of the given factor. These are shocks, for example, related to innovation or technological progress, introduced in this area.

Table 4

Granger causality test of the government securities and budget deficit

Granger c-dusaJLity wald tests

Equation Excluded chi2 df Prob > chi2

govtb def 2.4961 4 0 645

govtb ALL 2.4961 4 а 645

def govtb 1.8384 4 0 765

def ALL 1.B3B4 4 0 755

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

Source: calculated by the authors.

Figure 5 shows that the amount of government securities is the biggest for regression shocks.

In addition, Fig. 6 shows the changes in government internal debt, which suggests that an increase in the absolute values of government internal debt is not equal to an increase in the share of internal debt in GDP. This indicates that the total public debt is currently increasing mainly due to external borrowing.

In such a way:

1) there is a negative relationship between government securities and the monetary base, and hence the money supply;

2) there is no correlation between the government budget deficit and government securities;

3) there is a weak, but positive relationship between the fiscal deficit and the monetary base.

Thus, the mechanism for addressing fiscal deficit is rarely resolved through monetization mechanisms.

Table 5

VAR analysis of the impact of the state budget deficit on the state securities

Coef. Std. Eel. z E3-1 z 1 195% Conf. Interval]

tab

LI. -.0702561 .1117 934 -0.50 0 620 -.3401661 .207 6539

1.2. -.0596247 .1335205 0.45 0 655 -.3213357 .202 0364

L3. -.3599979 .1307 913 -2.75 0 006 -.616344 -.1036516

LI. -.3610712 .141307 9 -2.58 0 010 -.6410327 -.0071158

def

LI. .0391-373 .0217276 i.ao 0 072 -.0034379 .0017326

L2- .0359355 .021996 L.63 0 102 -.00717 96 .0790507

L3. .0361583 .0235236 1.54 0 124 -.0099472 .0022638

LI. .0259S36 .0250099 L.13 0 259 -.019135 .0710622

cons .0439091 ■00B331 5.27 0 000 .0275806 .060237 9

def

tab

1.1.. 1.021696 .0711134 L.17 0 241 -.6056545 1 .729047

L2. -.4052407 .0203375 -0.49 0 621 -2.013073 1.202591

L3. .5030956 .0035211 0. 63 0 531 -1.071777 2.077960

LI. .520096 .0 601307 0. 60 Û 54 9 -L.101409 2.221601

def

LI. -.4347203 .1334042 .4.26 0 001 -.6953525 .!73L04I

L2. -.4 9L8 619 .1351454 -3. 64 0 000 - .756742 -.2269B1B

LJ. -.4173965 .1145184 -2.6 9 0 004 -.7006474 -.1341157

LI. .5293657 .1413622 7.74 0 000 .252 4006 .8064306

cons -.034 9252 .051162 -0. 6B 0 495 -.13524 .0653996

Note: mb is the monetary base, def is the deficit. Source: calculated by the authors.

Fiscal dominance: government expenditure and inflation

The assessment of fiscal dominance through price control with a view to reducing the growth of public expenditure should begin with an analysis of monetary regulation in Armenia within the framework of inflation targeting. Since 2006, Armenia has officially adopted an inflation-targeting regime within monetary regulation. Base inflation was wet as a target and initially changed several times in value. The Central Bank of the Republic of Armenia has definitely set the inflation target of 4±1.5% since the end of 2007, which is still in force today. However, as a result of monetary regulation throughout the inflation targeting period, the Central Bank of Armenia rarely managed to achieve the set target (Fig. 7). Despite the fact that in most cases the monetary authorities failed to achieve the set goal, the Central Bank of Armenia never tried to change the target nominal anchor of monetary policy [19].

Neither core inflation nor the cumulative value of the price level falls within the definition of a central bank. The Armenian economy has been deflationary over the past four years, indicating rather tight monetary regulation, as well as a slowdown in economic

Table 6

Granger causality test of the monetary base and budget deficit

vargranger

Granger causality Wald tests

Equation Excluded chi2 df Prob > chi2

mb def 3.3639 4 0 424

rata AIL 3.3699 4 0 424

def Tub 1.9073 4 0 753

def All 1.9073 4 0 753

Source: calculated by the authors.

growth due to a significant decrease in consumption in the economy.

However, the inflation rate set by the Central Bank is significant for the government spending, since the latter requires mandatory annual indexation of price changes. From this perspective, keeping the prices as low as possible allows monetary regulation to solve fiscal problems.

As mentioned above, the state budget of Armenia is characterized by chronic budget deficits (Fig. 1). Let's consider these indicators for GDP (Fig. 8). The share of expenditures of the state budget of the Republic of Armenia in relation to the gross product has significantly increased since 2008. This is offset by an

20 10 a -10

varbasic. def. def

varbasic. def. govtb

varbasic, def, mb

varbasic, gcvtb, def

varbasic. govtb, govtb

varbasic, govtb. mb

varbasic, mb. def

varbasic, mb. govtb

varbasic, mb. mb

-r

2 4 6 SO

2 4 6

step

S 0

95% CI

impulse-response function (irf)

Graphs by irfname, impulse variable, and response variable

Fig. 4. Impulse-response function for following variables: budget deficit, government securities, monetary base

Source: calculated by the authors.

Fig. 5. Orthogonalized impulse-response function for the following variables: budget deficit, government securities, monetary base

Source: calculated by the authors.

Fig. 6. Government internal debt of the Republic of Armenia, billion AMD

Source: database of the National Statistical Service of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.armstat.am (accessed on 12.10.2020) and also calculated by the authors.

increase in the budget deficit due to the contraction of the economy as a whole as a result of fiscal revenues. Thus, the problem of increasing government revenues is quite obvious.

The reduction of budget expenditure is not an easy task, especially in developing economies. Fig. 9 shows the structure of government spending in Armenia. As you can see, the largest share of spending falls on social spending, defense and the state apparatus. These sections are difficult to cut down.

As a result, macroeconomic regulation urgently requires control of public spending. In the absence of stronger institutions, it is forced to address the problem through monetary intervention.

• Methodology: Characteristics of the relationship model between government spending and inflation

To determine the relationship between government spending and inflation, we used the model described in the work by S. Olubokun, E. Ayooluwade and F. O. Fawehinmi (2016) [20]. Equation 16 is a brief description of this model:

12

CPI (cumulative) CPI (core inflation) Target Target

III I III I III I III I III I III I III I III I III I III M^II^ I III I III I III

-3 | 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019

Fig. 7. CPI and Central Bank of Armenia monetary policy target, quarterly, %

Source: database of the Central Bank of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.cba.am (accessed on 12.10.2020).

40

30

20

10

■Government revenue

Government expanditure

Net balance

-10

Fig. 8. State budget of the Republic of Armenia, % of GDP

Source: database of the National Statistical Service of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.armstat.am (accessed on 12.10.2020).

General public services Economic relations Health care i Social security

100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0%

I Defence

i Environmental protection Rereation and Culture i Reserve fond

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

Public order and security Housing and public utilities Education

2015 2016 2017 2018

Fig. 9. State budget expenditure structure of Armenia

Source: database of the National Statistical Service of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.armstat.am (accessed on 12.10.2020).

7

2

0

Equation 16

k

a =Z4 xa,

i=1

where at is a column vector of observations of all variables in a model at t, ^ = V1 - V5 — are impulses, innovations and other shocks.

In particular, in the model presented in the above-mentioned paper variables Real GDP (RGDP), Total Government Expenditure (TGEP), Inflation (INFR), Money Supply (MSPL) and Exchange Rate (EXCH) (at= RGDP, TGEP, INFR, EXCH, MSPL) were used.

Equation 17 is disclosed in Equation 17:

Equation 17

RGDPt = Yi + y2 TGEP-1 + y3INFRt_i + y4EXCHt_i + + Y5MSPL-1 + Y6RGDPt_i + Vi,

TGEPt = 8i + 82TGEPt-1 + 83INFRt1 + 84EXCHt-1 + + 85MSPLt . + 8R.GDP, 1 + V2,

5 t -1 6 t - 2'

INFRt = a1 + a2TGEPt 1 + a3INFR t 1 + a4EXCHt 1 +

+ *5MSPL - 1 + *6R GDPt-1 + ^

EXCHt = pi + p2TGEP-i + P3INFR-1 + P4EXCH-1 + + PMSPL-i + WGDP-i + V

MSPLt = a1 + a2TGEPt-1 + a3INFR t-1 + a4EXCHt-1 + -i a5MSPLt . + a6RGDP t , + V5,

5 t-1 6 t-1 57

where y1- Y5 81- 85 a1-a5 P1-P5 and a1 - a5 are the parameters to be estimated.

The data were converted to stationary and normal distributions and a VAR model was built. The resulting model was considered by the authors both holis-tically and by individual regressions. Finally, the authors built a table of the impulse-response function, which made it possible to assess the influence of two separate indicators on each other.

• Testing the model of connection between public expenditure and inflationfor Armenia

We used the following data to build the model for Armenian economy: quarterly data on the exchange rate (exr), government expenditure (exp), inflation in the form of CPI (inf), money supply (m2) and real GDP (rgdp) from the first quarter of 2003 to the third quarter of 2019. Then, we calculated the differences between logarithms of this data, and checked them for stationarity by means of Dickie-Fuller test (Appendix, Table 6). We normalized time series (Appendix, Table 7). We then calculated the order criterion for the model (Appendix, Table 8). Thus, the third order was concluded to be the best choice for the model. The model produced the following points:

• government expenditure is affected by government expenditure itself with lags of 1, 2 and 3, and is

affected negatively, which is logical, because if in one quarter the authorities spend more money from the state budget, then in the next quarter they should cut their spending;

• the impact of exchange-rate volatility on government expenditure is also negative, if the dram to the dollar becomes more expensive, then government expenditure increases with the first lag;

• inflation is influenced positively by inflation itself, exchange rate volatility and changes in the money supply with the third lag;

• exchange rate volatility is affected positively, only by the exchange rate itself, with the first lag. The money supply is also affected by exchange-rate volatility with one lag, but negatively;

• real GDP is affected negatively, only by the real GDP itself through one lag (quarter).

The analysis of the impulse-response function (Fig. 10) and the orthogonalized impulse-response function (Fig. 11) showed that internal shocks are strongly responded by government expenditure (they respond to shock from government expenditure itself, exchange rates, inflation and money supply), real GDP (responds to shocks from exchange rate, inflation, money supply and real GDP itself), but the inflation response to changes in government expenditure is rather small.

The response of the indicators to external shocks almost coincides with the response to internal shocks, except government expenditure, which responds more to changes in real GDP than to changes in prices. The most significant factors for real GDP were exchange rate volatility inflation and exogenous changes in GDP itself.

The analysis showed that inflation does not react to internal and external shocks, which means that it is not subject to market mechanisms, but the high concentration in the market of goods in Armenia, as well as the active intervention of the Central Bank of Armenia in the currency market, as detailed in our previous studies. The analysis also supports this point, evidently indicating that the exchange rate of the national currency did not respond to any internal or external shocks included in the regression analysis, which may be due to non-market mechanisms of exchange rate formation of the dram and active currency regulation by monetary authorities of Armenia.

Finally, when examining GDP growth, GDP deflator and CPI, it can be seen that GDP growth is in most cases higher than GDP deflator growth, which in fact does not reflect either inflationary GDP growth or low consumption growth, where supply exceeds demand (Fig. 12). This dynamics reflects the lack of economic efficiency.

The developed model points to the ineffectiveness of monetary regulation within inflation targeting in

Fig. 10. Impulse-response function for the following variables: government expenditure, exchange rate, inflation, money supply, real GDP

Source: calculated by the authors.

Fig. 11. Orthogonalized impulse-response function for the following variables: government expenditure, exchange rate, inflation, money supply, real GDP

Source: calculated by the authors.

115

110

105

100

95

90

85

Growth of GDP CPI

GDP deflator

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019

Fig. 12. Growth of GDP, CPI and GDP deflator, annual, in %

Source: database of the National Statistical Service of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.armstat.am (accessed on 12.10.2020) and also calculated by the authors.

Fig. 13. Dynamics of USD\AMD rate in Armenia, monthly

Source: database of the Central Bank of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.cba.am (accessed on 12.10.2020).

Armenia, since monetary regulation aims at the fiscal objective of controlling the growth of state budget expenditures along with price level instability.

Fiscal dominance: public debt and exchange rate

Finally, the most notorious stumbling block between fiscal and monetary policy is the problem of public debt. While in theory this problem is being addressed by the Central Bank lending money to the government, in practice many countries use exchange-rate mechanisms.

As mentioned above, Armenia is pursuing an inflation targeting policy that assumes a freely floating exchange rate of the national currency. According to the Law of RA "On Currency Regulation and Currency Control",2 as

2 Cf The Law of RA on Currency Regulation and Currency Control. URL: http://www.parliament.am/legislation.php?sel=show&ID= 2140&lang=eng (accessed on 05.05.2020).

well as the IMF3 classification, Armenia is included in the group with a regulated free floating rate. In addition, the Law notes the possibility of the Central Bank's intervention in the foreign exchange market, in case it is necessary to achieve the goals of monetary regulation.

The assessment of foreign exchange regulation in Armenia testifies to the active intervention of the Central Bank in the foreign exchange market and in the formation of the dram exchange rate. Figure 13 shows the dynamics of the exchange rate by month. Despite significant external and internal shocks for the economy, the AMD exchange rate has demonstrated stable volatility over the past few

3 CF Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2018; International Monetary Fund. Monetary and Capital Markets Department, April, 2019. URL: https://www. imf.org/en/Publications/Annual-Report-on-Exchange-Ar-rangements-and-Exchange-Restrictions/Issues/2019/04/24/ Annual-Report-on-Exchange-Arrangements-and-Exchange-Restrictions-2018-46162 (accessed on 12.05.2020).

12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2000

I Government of RA Central Bank of RA I Banks I Other sectors I Inter-firm credit and loans

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 20182019

Fig. 14. Gross external debt of RA, million USD

Source: database of the National Statistical Service of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.armstat.am (accessed on 12.10.2020).

75 60 45 30 15 0

-External government debt (% of GDP) -Internal government debt (% of GDP) Gross government debt (% of GDP)

600 450 300 150 0

1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018

Fig. 15. Government debt of RA (in % of GDP) and exchange rate of AMD

Source: database of the National Statistical Service of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.armstat.am (accessed on 12.10.2020).

years [19]. Many of our researches prove that such stability has been and is currently ensured by efforts of monetary authorities [20]. The analysis of the formation factors of the exchange rate indicates a rather low participation of market factors in this process, while the role of monetary authorities is big [21, 22].

Maintaining the exchange rate at a certain point aims at several objectives. Among the most significant are the maintenance of prices and the resolution of the public debt problem.

As we can see in Fig. 14, Armenia's external debt amounts to almost $ 12 billion and is equivalent to above 85% of GDP. More than half of the debt is in the government sector.

As of 2018, the share of total government debt in GDP was 55.7%, including 44.5% of external debt and 11.2% of domestic debt (Fig. 15). According to the Fig., over the past 10 years, Armenia's total public debt has increased twice: after 2008 and 2014. Both periods were caused by external shocks, which had a negative impact on the macroeconomic situation in Armenia and demanded an increase in the country's external debt to offset the loss of economic growth. Since the end of 2014, the Ar-

menian government has been actively raising domestic debt obligations.

The problem of Armenia's high government debt is obvious and certainly requires both regulation and solution. Monetary policy is actively involved in solving this problem now. If the Central Bank of Armenia stimulated the investment of the financial system in government securities by the Armenian government, using supervisory functions on the part of the internal debt, then, in our opinion, it is pursuing a policy of gimmicks on the external debt to maintain the exchange rate at a stable level, conceived to the detriment of the country's export positions and the competitiveness of the domestic product in foreign markets, including the EAEU market. In this regard, a model of the relationship between the public debt and the exchange rate of the national currency in order to identify this relationship in the Armenian economy is presented below.

• Methodology: Characteristics of the model of the relationship between public debt and the exchange rate

In order to identify the dependence of exchange rate volatility in a country's government debt, we propose the following model: a country with a similar structure

0

Table 7

Correlation between variables

. corr exc ml cpi exp imp gdp debt (obs=86)

exr ml cpi exp imp gdp debt

exr 1.0000

ml -0.0430 1 0000

cpi -0.1722 -0 2795 L 0000

exp 0.2262 -0 0077 0 0594 1.0000

imp 0.2565 -0 0375 0 0 654 0.0410 1.0000

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

sop 0.1332 0 0509 -0 0393 0.2172 0.2775 1,0000

dcbl -П.6851 0 1393 0 0794 -0.0060 0.00L9 -0.1565 1.0000

Table 8

Regression model with the dependent variable of exchange rate

reg exr cpi ini]i debt

'uroe s 5 df MS

Modal .131414091 .3 .C43R046 97

Re3idijal .105242774 82 .001283448

tot .al B!> .002/84198

Number of ; >1: Fi 3, 02> Prob F R-squared Adj R-squared

Root MSE

B6 34.13 0.0000 0.5553 0.5390 .03583

exr Coef. Std. Err. t P>|tl i 951 fV.nf. Interval]

cpi - .C073BB5 .0040153 -1 84 0. 069 -.0153762 .0005991

imp -3160451. .0867879 3 64 о. ООО ,143396 £ .4806944

debt -.5016812 . 0 54 3219 -4 13 D. 000 -.6109383 -.3924241

cons .0071309 .0046241 1 55 (). 124 -.0020173 • Dl 63797

Table 9

Heteroskedasticity and omitted variables test

. estat hettest

Breusch-Pagan / Cook-Weis berg test for heteroskedasticity Ho: Constant variance Variables: fitted values of exr

chl2(l) = 0.15

Prob > chi2 = 0,7007

. estat ovtest

Ramsey RESET test using powers of the fitted values of exr Ho: model has no emitted variables

F<3, 79) Prob > F

1.02 0 .3886

and internal and external shock to the economy was selected as a benchmark. The choice was also based on the implementation of inflation targeting policies in the context of a regulated floating exchange rate. In addition, the country's trade route options as well as the structure of GDP were included in the country's selection criteria. Based on the above criteria, we chose the Hungarian economy to build the basic model, which applies inflation targeting in a floating exchange rate framework,4

4 Cf. Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2018; International Monetary Fund. Monetary and Capital Markets Department. April, 2019. URL: https://www. imf.org/en/Publications/Annual-Report-on-Exchange-Ar-rangements-and-Exchange-Restrictions/Issues/2019/04/24/

has no access to the sea and two major industries are metallurgy and textiles.

Based on the analysis of monetary and exchange rate policy in Hungary, a model was built that describes the relationship between the country's public debt and the volatility of exchange rates of national units.

To build the currency volatility, we used quarterly data from the first quarter of 1998 to the third quarter of 2019 on the following indicators: GDP, Ml cash aggregate (cash + demand deposits), inflation (CPI), exchange rate, export and import, and government debt. The

Annual-Report-on-Exchange-Arrangements-and-Exchange-Restrictions-2018-46162 (accessed on 18.03.2020).

-0,2

Fig. 16. Volatility of real exchange rate of the dram and exchange rate of the dram on the model examined

Source: database of the Central Bank of the Republic of Armenia. URL: www.cba.am (accessed on 12.10.2020) and also calculated by the authors.

data have been seasonally cleared, differences between logarithms of current and previous periods have been calculated and then the data have been normalized (Appendix, Table 9).

First, we tested the correlation between variables to avoid the multicollinearity. The highest correlation is between imports and GDP, imports and exports, inflation and money supply (Table 7). Since the exchange rate is more closely correlated with imports than with export or GDP, we decided to keep imports, monetary inflation and inflation rate in the model along the same lines.

We built a regression model with the remaining variables (Table 8).

The model is acceptable (R 2 = 0.5552), which means that exchange rate volatility is explained by data variables with probability more than 50%. To validate the model, we tested the model for heteroscedasticity (Breusch-Pagan test) and lack of significant variables (Ramsey test) in addition to lack of multicollinearity. The test results made us conclude that there is no heteroskedasticity and that there are no significant variables omitted (Table 9).

The model was adopted for testing in the Armenian economy.

• Testing the model of connection between government debt and exchange rate for Armenia

Exchange rate volatility equation for the Hungarian economy:

Equation 19

ExR = -0.0073885 * CPI + 0.3160456 * Imp -- 0.5016812 "Debt

Using Equation 19, we analyzed and assessed the impact of government debt on the exchange rate of the dram.

Figure 16 shows the analysis of the movement of the exchange rate using the formula and the real exchange rate. The data used in the model does not have a season-

ality factor, and each variable is the difference between the current and the previous period of the logarithms (all variables except the CPI) of the variable values. The volatility of the dram exchange rate is also seasonally adjusted. We conclude that the exchange rate volatility of the Hungarian forint against the US dollar (Exr_h) is not similar to the exchange rate volatility of the dram against the US dollar (Exr_a). Thus, the Armenian exchange rate is not regulated by the same regime as the Hungarian exchange rate, even if both Armenia and Hungary have a floating exchange rate regime. Thus, the volatility of the dram is due to non-market factors, which indicates the intervention of the Central Bank of Armenia in the foreign exchange market of Armenia.

In addition to meeting the targets, non-market interference shows that monetary authorities also indirectly engage in fiscal regulation to keep external debt at a certain level.

CONCLUSION

Fiscal dominance in the Armenian economy is clearly present to some extent. For sure, monetary policy aims to achieve stable prices in the country. However, the target chosen greatly facilitates the adoption of regulatory instruments, and the intended target directly solves the problems of fiscal policy.

The developed models have proved that all three mechanisms of fiscal dominance are used in monetary regulation by the Central Bank of Armenia. The most pronounced are fiscal expenditure, as well as external government debt. Clearly, the priority of these objectives in macroeconomic regulation requires fiscal dominance. However, given the negative consequences for economic growth and well-being of the population in the long term, we believe that the chosen approach in the country's macroeconomic policy should be revised.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

The study was funded by a research grant from the Ministry of Education and Science of the Russian Federation.

Russian-Armenian University, Yerevan, Armenia.

REFERENCES

1. Leeper E. M. Equilibria under 'active' and 'passive' monetary policies. Journal of Monetary Economics. 1991;27(1):129-147. DOI: 10.1016/0304-3932(91)90007-B

2. Sims C. A. A simple model to study the determination of the price level and the interaction of monetary and fiscal policy. Economic Theory. 1994;4(3):381-399. DOI: 10.1007/BF01215378

3. Woodford M. Monetary policy and price level determinacy in a cash-in-advance economy. Economic Theory. 1994;4(3):345-380. DOI: 10.1007/BF01215377

4. Woodford M. Price-level determinacy without control of a monetary aggregate. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. 1995;43:1-46. DOI: 10.1016/0167-2231(95)90033-0

5. Bassetto M. Fiscal theory of the price level. 2008. URL: https://users.nber.org/~bassetto/research/palgrave/ ftheorypost.pdf

6. Bassetto M., Cui W. The fiscal theory of the price level in a world of low interest rates. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 2018;89:5-22. DOI: 10.1016/j.jedc.2018.01.006

7. Taylor J. B. Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. 1993;39:195-214. DOI: 10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-L

8. Buiter W. H. The fiscal theory of the price level: A critique. The Economic Journal. 2002;112(481):459-480. DOI: 10.1111/1468-0297.00726

9. Bohn H. The behavior of U.S. public debt and deficits. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1998;113(3):949-963. DOI: 10.1162/003355398555793

10. De Resende C. Cross-country estimates of the degree of fiscal dominance and central bank independence. Bank of Canada Working Paper. 2007;(36). URL: https://www.banqueducanada.ca/wp-content/uploads/2010/02/wp07-36. pdf

11. Jevdovic G., Milenkovic I. Monetary versus fiscal dominance in emerging European economies. Facta Universitatis. Series: Economics and Organization. 2018;15(2):125-133. DOI: 10.22190/FUEO1802125J

12. Sanusi K., Akinlo A. Investigating fiscal dominance in Nigeria. Journal of Sustainable Development. 2016;9(1):125-131. DOI: 10.5539/jsd.v9n1p125

13. Fratianni M., Spinelli F. Fiscal dominance and money growth in Italy: The long record. Explorations in Economic History. 2001;38(2):252-272. DOI: 10.1006/exeh.2000.0753

14. Khan H., Marimuthu M., Lai F.-W. Fiscal deficit and its less inflationary sources of borrowing with the moderating role of political instability: Evidence from Malaysia. Sustainability. 2020;12(1):366. DOI: 10.3390/su12010366

15. Ali K., Khalid M. Sources to finance fiscal deficit and their impact on inflation: A case study of Pakistan. Pakistan Development Review. 2019;58(1):27-43. DOI: 10.30541/v58i1pp.27-43

16. Mehrara M., Soufiani M. B., Rezael S. The impact of government spending on inflation through the inflationary environment, STR approach. World Scientific News. 2016;37:153-167

17. Voskanyan M. A., Galstyan A. G. The inflation targeting trap and its influence on economic growth: Armenian case. Upravlenets = The Manager. 2017;(5):72-88. DOI: 10.29141/2218-5003-2017-7-5-9

18. Olubokun S., Ayooluwade E., Fawehinmi F. O. Government expenditure, inflation rate and economic growth in Nigeria (1981-2013): A vector autoregressive approach. Romanian Journal of Fiscal Policy. 2016;7(1):1-12.

19. Voskanyan M. A. The crises in the currency market of Armenia: Causes and consequences. Upravlenets = The Manager. 2016;(2):10-15. (In Russ.).

20. Sandoyan E. M., Voskanyan M. A., Barsegyan M., Mnatsakanyan L. A. "Theory of communicating vessels": The problem of currency regulation. Transition Studies Review. 2014;21(1):113-131. DOI: 10.14665/1614-4007-21-1007

21. Voskanyan M. A. Factors in the formation of the exchange rate: The case of Armenia. In: Growth potential of the modern economy: Opportunities, risks, strategies. Proc. 5th Int. sci.-pract. conf. Moscow: Witte Moscow University; 2018:1183-1190. (In Russ.).

22. Sandoyan E. M., Voskanyan M. A., Galstyan A. G. Assessment of key factors of the foreign exchange rate formation in Armenia. Finansy: teoriya i praktika = Finance: Theory and Practice. 2018;22(5):27-39. DOI: 10.26794/2587-56712018-22-5-27-39

APPENDIX

Table 1

Test of the data distributions

swilk def govtb mb

Shapiro-Wilk W test far normal data

Variable Cbs w V z l'rob>z

def 46 0. 9537 B 2 036 1 .509 0.06566

qovtb 4 6 0. 97535 1 0B 6 0.175 0.43060

mb 45 0. 3668 7 1 900 1.362 0.08661.

sfrancia def govtb inb

Shapiro-Francia W" test for normal data

Variable Obs Hi' V' z L,rob>z

def 46 0 9533L 2 279 1 . 54 9 0 06067

qovtb 46 0 9B382 0 790 -0. 4 4 3 0 67126

Hifci 46 0 96526 695 0. 992 0 16058

Table 2

Test of stationarity

. dfuller def

Dickey-Fuller test for unit root

Number of obs

- Interpolated Dickey-Fuller -

Test 1% Critical 5% Critical 10% critical

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

Statistic Value Value Value

Z(t>

-9.273

-3.614

-2.944

MacKinnon approximate p-value for Z (t) = 0.0000 . dfuller govtb

Dickey-Fuller test for unit root Ntoraber of obs

- Interpolated Dickey-Fuller -

Test 1% Critical 5% Critical 10% Critical

Statistic Value Value Value

Z{t)

-14.971

-3.614

-2.944

MacKinnon approximate p-value foe Z|t} = 0.0000 . dfuller rab

Dickey-Fuller test for unit root Number of obs

45

- Interpolated Dickey-Fuller --

Test 1% Critical 5% Critical 10% Critical

Statistic Value Value Value

Z[t>

-3,614

-2.944

MacKinnon approximate p-value for Z It} - 0.0000

Table 3

Selection-order criteria test

varsoc mb gov

Selection-order criteria Sample: 2009ql - 2019q2

Number of obs

lag LL LR llf [' FPE AIC (QIC SBIC

0 20.454 .001424 87876 _ .01843 -.796013

1 37.6212 34.339 4 0 000 .000761 * -1 50587* -1 .41488* -1.25763*

2 35.1357 3.0249 4 0 .0008 58 -1 38741 -1 .23 571"; -.973682

3 44.3146 10.350* 4 0 03 5 .000814 -1 4 4 356 -1 . 23126 -.064 311

4 43.4244 a.2191 4 0 084 .000816 -1 44879 -1 .17581 -.704065

Endogenous: mb govtb Exogenous: _cons

Table 4

Selection-order criteria test

varsoc gov def

Selection-order criLeria

Sample: 2009ql - 2019q2 Number of obs = 42

1 ag LL LR df p FPE AIC HQ ] С SB IС

0 -82.9472 .195806 4.0451 4.07543 4.12785

1 -66.5337 32.827 4 0 000 .10847 3.4 533« 3.544 97 3.70222

2 -61.41Ы 10.237 4 0 037 .103027 3.4 0072 3.55237 3.81445

3 -39.6354 43.56 4 0 ooo .04436 2.55406 2.7 6637 3.13329

4 -31.9047 15.461' 4 0 004 .037409* 2.37641* 2.64938* 3.12113*

Selection-order criteria test

. varsoc nib def

Table 5

Selection-order criteria Sample: 2009ql - 2019q2

Number of obs

leg LL LR df p FPE AIC HQIC SBIC

0 52.1963 .000314 -2.3903 -2.35997 -2.30755

1 55.24 31 6.0937 4 0 192 .000329 -2.34491 -2.23392 -2.09667

2 60.3691 10.252 4 0 03 6 .000312 -2.39853 -2.24688 -1.9848

3 85.427 50.116 4 0 000 .000115 -3.40129 -3.183 98 -2.82206

4 95.5631 20.272* 4 0 ООО .000086* -3.69348* -3.42052* -2.94877*

Table 6

Table 7

Testing variables for stationarity

! p-value for Z (tj = 0.0094

. dfuller rgdp

Dickey-Fuller test for unit root

Humber of obs

- Interpolated Dicfcey-Fullet

1% Critical 5% Critical 10%

Value Value

Critical Value

Test of the data distribution

5wilk exp inf exr m2 rgdp

ShapLro-Wilk W test for normal data

Variable Obs W V z Prob>z

exp 66 0 os os г 1 Ht 0.291 0.38566

inf 66 15 96633 15 eo2 -0.4 78 0.66368

exr 66 15 96917 1 809 1 . 285 0.09940

ni? ьь 15 ч 6 as; 1 И ! 1.33» 0.09174

гдф 66 15 965 7 0 S 007 1 .510 0.0654 7

sfrancia exp inf exr ro2 rgdp

Shapiro-Francia W test for normal data

Variable Obs w V' z Probes

exp 66 D 97334 1 731 l (556 0.14558

inf 66 0 99D5 7 0 612 -0 94 G 0.B2744

exr 66 D 96793 2 078 1 408 0.07062

ne 66 0 06735 2 120 1 446 0.07412

гдф 66 0 9721 9 1 80S 1 37 0.12784

Selection-order criteria test

varsoc exp inf exr m2 rgdp

Selection-order criteria Sample: 2004ql - 2019q2

Table 8

Number of obs

1лд LL LR df p FPF. A p.": KQIC SB 11.

0 ; " 3 de-14 -15 8 688 -15 U 014 -15.6572

1 56 :./24 133.59 25 0 000 2 -1? 2169* -16 81;J:i< -16.1376*

2 577.237 21.026 25 0 555 3 4e-14 -16 8464 -16 105 5 -14. 9594

593-031 31.538 25 0 171. 4 ïe-14 -16 '■4 94 -15 4717 13.3047

4 61 ;s.û27 01 . 992* 25 0 001 5 0e-14 -16 5315 -15 1 671 -12.9791

Endogenous: Exogenous:

exp inf exr m2 rgdp cons

I approximate p-value for Z(t) - 0.0000

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

Table 9

Test of the data distribution

swilk ml cpi exr exp imp gdp debt

Shapiro-Wilk W test foc normal data

Variable Obs w V z Prob>z

ml 86 0- .97358 1. .924 1. . 4 40 0.07491

cpi 86 0. .98465 1, .118 0. .246 0.40294

exr 86 0- .99031 0. .706 -0. .766 0.77816

exp 86 0. .97602 1, .747 1 .227 0,10984

imp 86 0, .98240 1. .282 0. .546 0.29242

gdp 86 0. .97735 1, . 650 1 . 1Û1 0.13535

debt 86 0- .97960 1. .486 0. .871 0.19182

about THE authors / ИНФОРМАЦИЯ ОБ АВТОРАХ

Mariam A. Voskanyan — Dr. Sci. (Econ.), Assoc. Prof., Head of Department of Economics and Finance, Russian-Armenian University, Institute of Economics and Business, Yerevan, Armenia

Мариам Амбарцумовна Восканян — доктор экономических наук, доцент, заведующая кафедрой экономики и финансов, Российско-армянский университет, Институт экономики и бизнеса, Ереван, Армения mariam.voskanyan@rau.am, voskanyanm@gmail.com

Lilit V. Paronyan — Bachelor student, Russian-Armenian University, Institute of Economics and Business, Yerevan, Armenia

Лилит Ваагновна Паронян — бакалавр, Российско-армянский университет, Институт экономики и бизнеса, Ереван, Армения lilit.paronyan@rau.am, lilitparonyan8@gmail.com

The article was submitted on 07.09.2020; revised on 21.09.2020 and accepted for publication on 22.09.2020. The authors read and approved the final version of the manuscript.

Статья поступила в редакцию 07.09.2020; после рецензирования 21.09.2020; принята к публикации 22.09.2020.

Авторы прочитали и одобрили окончательный вариант рукописи.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.