Научная статья на тему 'DYNAMIC SPICE-MODEL OF RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN MARKETING NETWORKS'

DYNAMIC SPICE-MODEL OF RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN MARKETING NETWORKS Текст научной статьи по специальности «Математика»

CC BY
4
2
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
Область наук
Ключевые слова
DIFFERENTIAL STACKELBERG GAMES / MARKETING / OPINION CONTROL ON NETWORKS / RESOURCE ALLOCATION

Аннотация научной статьи по математике, автор научной работы — Agieva Movlatkhan T., Gorbaneva Olga I.

We consider a dynamic Stackelberg game theoretic model of the coordination of social and private interests (SPICE-model) of resource allocation in marketing networks. The dynamics of controlled system describes an interaction of the members of a target audience (basic agents) that leads to a change of their opinions (cost of buying the goods and services of firms competing on a market). An interaction of the firms (influence agents) is formalized as their differential game in strategic form. The payoff functional of each firm includes two terms: the summary opinion of the basic agents with consideration of their marketing costs (a common interest of all firms), and the income from investments in a private activity. The latter income is described by a linear function. The firms exert their influence not to all basic agents but only to the members of strong subgroups of the influence digraph (opinion leaders). The opinion leaders determine the stable final opinions of all members of the target audience. A coordinating principal determines the firms' marketing budgets and maximizes the summary opinion of the basic agents with consideration of the allocated resources. The Nash equilibrium in the game of influence agents and the Stackelberg equilibrium in a general hierarchical game of the principal with them are found. It is proved that the value of opinion of a basic agent is the same for all influence agents and the principal. It is also proved that the influence agents assign less resources for the marketing efforts than the principal would like.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.

Текст научной работы на тему «DYNAMIC SPICE-MODEL OF RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN MARKETING NETWORKS»

Contributions to Game Theory and Management, XIII, 8-23

Dynamic SPICE-Model of Resource Allocation in Marketing

Networks*

Movlatkhan T. Agieva1 and Olga I. Gorbaneva2

1 Ingush State University, Magistralnaya St. 39, Nazran, 386132, Russia

E-mail: agieva25@mail.ru

2 South Federal University,

J.I. Vorovieh Institute of Mathematics, Mechanics and Computer Sciences, Milchakov St. 8a, Rostov-on-Don, 344090, Russia E-mail: gorbaneva@mail.ru

Abstract We consider a dynamic Stackelberg game theoretic model of the coordination of social and private interests (SPICE-model) of resource allocation in marketing networks. The dynamics of controlled system describes an interaction of the members of a target audience (basic agents) that leads to a change of their opinions (cost of buying the goods and services of firms competing on a market). An interaction of the firms (influence agents) is formalized as their differential game in strategic form. The payoff functional of each firm includes two terms: the summary opinion of the basic agents with consideration of their marketing costs (a common interest of all firms), and the income from investments in a private activity. The latter income is described by a linear function. The firms exert their influence not to all basic agents but only to the members of strong subgroups of the influence digraph (opinion leaders). The opinion leaders determine the stable final opinions of all members of the target audience. A coordinating principal determines the firms' marketing budgets and maximizes the summary opinion of the basic agents with consideration of the allocated resources. The Nash equilibrium in the game of influence agents and the Stackelberg equilibrium in a general hierarchical game of the principal with them are found. It is proved that the value of opinion of a basic agent is the same for all influence agents and the principal. It is also proved that the influence agents assign less resources for the marketing efforts than the principal would like.

Keywords: differential Stackelberg games, marketing, opinion control on networks, resource allocation.

1. Introduction

Models of influence and opinion control on networks are widespread in the literature in the last several decades (Chkhartishvili, Gubanov and Novikov, 2019; Jackson, 2008). The approach most close to the authors' one is presented in the papers (Sedakov and Zhen, 2019; Zhen, 2019). In those models a network is described by a weighted directed graph in which the vertices represent the members of the network (basic agents), and the weights of the arcs reflect an intensity of their mutual influence. The basic agents have their opinions about an issue which can change in time due to the network interaction. External influence agents can impact the basic agents in their own interests. We suppose the following. First, it is rational to exert control impact not to all basic agents but only to the members

* The work was supported by the Russian Science Foundation, project № 17-19-01038.

of strong subgroups of the influence digraph (opinion leaders). It is known that the opinion leaders determine the stable final opinions of all basic agents. Second, we consider marketing networks in which the opinions of basic agents are their costs of buying of the goods and services providing by firms competing on a market (influence agents), and control variables of the influence agents are their marketing efforts directed to the opinion leaders (Agieva, Korolev and Ougolnitsky, 2019).

Models of coordination of the social and private interests, including their dynamic formulation, are studied in the public economics (Long, 2010). In those models it is supposed that each agent divides his efforts between a private activity and the production of a good which is common for all agents. In turn, the agent's payoff is a sum of the income from his private activity and his share in the utility from the production of the common good. The author's formulation of the models of coordination of social and private resources (SPICE-models) is given in (Gorbaneva, 2019), and some examples of the application of SPICE-models in different problem domains are described in (Anopchenko and others, 2019a; Anopchenko and others, 2019b; Sukhinov, Ougolnitsky and Usov, 2020; Ugol'nitskii and Usov, 2020).

An important aspect of the control in complex systems consists in the evaluation of a degree of coordination between the active agents. The most known formulation is the problem of inefficiency of equilibria when the global maximal value of the function of social welfare is compared with its value in the worst of Nash equilibria in a game of the agents (Nisan, Roughgarden, Tardos and Vazirani, 2007).

This paper is based on the mentioned streams of research and makes the following contribution. We consider a hierarchical dynamic SPICE-model of resource allocation in a marketing network. The dynamics of opinions of the basic agents (members of the target audience) is determined by their interaction and marketing efforts of several competing firms (influence agents) that form the lower control level. The payoff functional of each firm includes two terms: the summary opinion of all basic agents with consideration of the marketing cost (a common interest of all influence agents), and the income from investments in a private activity. The latter income is described by a linear function. It is assumed that in the stage of analysis of the network the members of its strong subgroups (opinion leaders) are already found, and the firms exert marketing influence only on them. On the upper control level a coordinating principal is situated. The principal allocates marketing budgets between the firms (influence agents) for the maximization of the summary-opinion of the basic agents. The unique Nash equilibrium in the game of influence agents in strategic form and the unique Stackelberg equilibrium in the game of the principal with them are found. The evaluation of the degree of coordination between the principal and the influence agents is made by means of a special system compatibility index (Sukhinov, Ougolnitsky and Usov, 2020).

In Section 2 we describe the SPICE-model of resource allocation in marketing networks, precise its specifics, and characterize the used methods. In Section 3 the Nash equilibrium in the differential game of influence agents in strategic form is built. In Section 4 the solution of the differential Stackelberg game between the principal and the influence agents is built. In section 5 the system compatibility index is calculated. Section 6 concludes and contains the directions of future research.

2. Dynamical Hierarchical SPICE-Model

The hierarchical dynamic SPICE-model of resource allocation in a marketing network has the form:

Jo ( {{uj>n=i>m=i, {xj}n=i) =

/■T

e

o

Y.xj (t) -E ri(t) j=i

¿=i

dt —>• max,

(1)

ri (t) > 0,^rfc (t) < R,

k=1

Ji ( ri, {uj}n=1, {xj}n=1) =

(2)

= JQ e-pt ^ ^(t) - ¿ uj (t) j + ¿[xj (t) - sjuj (t)] j dt ^ max, (3)

n

0 <53uj(t) < ri(t),i = l,...,m;t G [0,T]; (4)

j=i

m n

ij = hj\j uj(t) + a'jx'(t)' xj(0) = xj0'j =1 • • • 'n' (5)

(6)

i=i

i=i

1, bj > 0, 0, bj = 0.

Thus, (l)-(6) is a differential Stackelberg game of the principal with several influence agents (firms). Here n is a number of basic agents (a number of target audience), m - a number of influence agents (competing firms), R - a total marketing budget of the leader, T - a length of the game, J0, Ji - the payoff functional of the leader and the influence agents respectively, r¿(t) - a marketing budget allocated to the i-th influence agent % the leader in the moment of time t, xj (t) - an opinion of the j-th basic agent in the moment t (cost of buying of goods and services), uj(t) -expenditures of the i-th influence agent for the marketing impact (advertizing and so on) to the j-th basic agent in the moment t, aij ct coefficient of influence of the i-th basic agent to the j-th basic agent, bj - a coefficient of influence of the i-th influence agent to the j-th basic agent, 5 denotes a discount factor, i.e. 5 = e-p. As different firms can exert influence to different members of the strong subgroups,

i

j-th basic agent then bj = 0 sj characterizes the connection of the i -th agent of influence and the j -th basic agent.

t

to the influence agents. Each of the agents receives a value of resources ri (t) that is a continuous function r¿(t) : [0, T] ^ [0, R]. The budget constraint means that 2m i r (t) — R- After receiving the resources ri (t) from the Principal the influence agents use them in private and common interests. The common interests are modeled by the function uj (t) which describes the share of the ¿-th influence agent's resources

jt continuous functions uj (t) : [0, T] ^ [0, ri(t)] are the strategies of the ¿-th influence

agent which satisfy the budget constraint uj (t) < n (t). The marketing impact includes advertizing, special actions, discounts, gifts, and so on.

A common (social) interest of the influence agents is modeled as maximization of the summary opinion of the basic agents, and their private interests are represented by the income from an activity which is not concerned with marketing efforts (for example, the private investments). We used the linear functions of the private activity, i.e. pi(x) = p • x, where p > 0 is a constant value. In turn, the principal maximizes the summary opinion of all basic agents minus the cost of resources allocated to the firms.

The unique Nash equilibrium in the game of influence agents in strategic form and the unique Stackelberg equilibrium in the game of the principal with them are found analytically by the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equations.

3. Building the Nash Equilibrium in the Game of Influence Agents

Let us investigate the problem of the i-th firm (3)-(6). The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation is

pV - ^ = max I V [xj (t) - sjuj (t)] + p | n (t) - V uj (t) I + dt ul- ,1<7<n I . _ I . _ '

j' <J< \3=1 \ 3=1

+ y dVi

XX v uk W + X a'qXl .fc=l i=l

(7)

with condition 0 — uj(t) — r(t)- Maximization by uj j = 1, 2,..., n, bj = 0

gives

. Ri(t) (bjfx1)2

uj (t) = -Vj 7 ,2 , (8)

Zjbj =0 ^jôxj

where =o uj (t) = R.(t) — r.(t).

3 v

Notice that we can substitute the expression uj (t) =- f~dv"\2 by uj (t) =

)2 , n ,

= n / . \2, and the expression R(t) = Xj.bi =o uj(t) by Rj(t) = Sj=1 uj(t),

as if bj = 0 then the summand ^bjfV^) e(lual to zero and can be inserted

in the common sum. Therefore, j (bjfg)2 = j=0 (bj^Similarly,

uj(t) = ^j.bj=0 uj(t), as if bj = 0 then uj(t) = 0. We consider the case when

the product of all bj is not equal to zero, otherwise the problem has no practical sense (there is no influence).

Let us use the linear Bellman functions

n

V (x,t) = X aj (t)xj + ^(t), j=1

then we can write the equation (7) with consideration of (8) as

n n

p^>j (t)xj + p^t) - £ a«(t)xj - p£'i(t) = j=1 j=i n l n \ n n

= 53 Xj (t) - Ri(t)+ Pi • (ri (t) -53 uj (t)| + aj (t)aij XI +

j=1 \ j=i / I=1 j=i

. v^Rk^iak(t)j| VVaj (t)bk ( k ( ^ j ( ) j . (9)

k=1 j=1 y2j=i K (t)bj)

Equating in the left and right hand sides of the equation (9) the coefficients at the first power of x, we receive the following differential equations for the coefficients a:

n

paj (t) - aj(t) = 1 + £ ai(t)j, j = 1, 2, ...,n. (10)

I=i

Rewrite the system of equations (10) in the matrix form

a'j = (pJ - A)aj - e, (11)

where A = {aij}i=1 2 n.j=1 2 n is the influence matrix, ai - the column vector of the coefficients aj, j = 1, 2,..., n, J - the unit matrix, e - n-dimensional column vector of units. System (11) is the same for all influence agents, therefore aj(t) = = (t) = ... = am(t) = aj(t) for any basic agent j = 1, 2,..., n, and from this point we will omit the superscript i of the coefficients aj.

Solving the system of differential equations (10), we receive:

a = (pJ - A)-1e, a = e(pI-A)tC +(pJ - A)-1 e.

The column vector of the constants of integration is found from the boundary-conditions:

a(T ) = 0,

therefore

a = -e(PI-A)(t-T)(pJ - A)-1 e + (pJ - A)-1e = (e^-A)(T-t) - j) (A - pJ)-1 e. t=0

a(0) = (>i-A)T - j) (A - pJ)-1e. (12)

Considering that aj(t) = ak (t) for any k =1, 2,..., n, we rewrite (9) in the form:

nnn

p^aj (t)xj + p^(t) - ^ aji(t)xj - ^ (t) ^^ Xj (t) - Ri (t) +

j=1 j=1 j=1

+Pi • (ri (t) - Ri(t)) + aj (t)aijx; + V/Rfc(t)

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

j

I=1j=1 k=1

EK (t)j2

j=1

Choosing the maximal value of the right hand side of (7) in dependence of the sum Rj (t), we have

-R(t) + pi • (ri(t) - R(t)) ^ VRi(t)

X(aj (t)bj) ^ max,

j=i

(13)

and

(ñi(t))r

E"=i (bj aj (t))2

4(1+ pi)2 •

Thus, the value R(t) in (13) with consideration of (4) is equal to

R (t) = min •

sn=i(bj aj (t))2

4(1+ Pi)2

; r (M.

Let us call the amount aj (t) the opinion value of the j-th basic agent for the i-th influence agent. In fact, in the Bellman function of the i-th influence agent V®(x, t) = j=i aj (t)xj + ft®(t), the factor aj (t) is a weight coefficient of the opinion of the respective basic agent xj. Thus, from the condition aj (t) = aj (t) we receive

Proposition 1. The opinion value of each basic agent is the same for all influence agents.

Equating the constant terms in the left and right hand sides of (9), we receive the differential equation for ft®:

ßrt(t) - pft¿(t) = v/Rkw

k=1

]T(aj (t)j 2 + Pi R(t) + R(t). (14)

j=i

The equation (14) is solved by the method of variation of parameters: !■ T

ßi(t) = Jt e

For t = 0 we have

ßi (0)

-p(r-t)

z.

k=1

Rk(r) X (aj(t)j2 - (pi + 1)R(t)dr.

j=i

-pr

X

k=1

Rk(r) X (aj(r)j2 - (pi + 1)R(r)dr,

j=i

where for any k = 1, 2,..., n (in particular, for the given i) we have

' E"=i(bj (t))2 . ^n \2

Rk(t) H (t))2 ^ 4(1+pk)2rfc(t)

fc() 1 jj, -

Thus, the maximal payoff of the influence agent is

rk(t), E"=i(bkaj(t))2 < 4(1+ pfc)2rfc(t).

(15)

max Ji = Vi(x(0), 0) = X a^' (0)xj- (0) +

uj >i<j<" j=i

+e

-pr

X

k=i

Rk(r) X (aj(r)j)2 - (pi + 1)R(r)dr,

j=i

e

0

where the components aj (0), j = 1, 2,..., n of the vector a(0) are determined by the expression (12), and Rk(r), k = 1, 2,..., m are determined by the expression (15). The control values are determined by the expression (8):

i(t) =

Ri(t) (bjaj(t)) E"=1 (bjaj(i)):

where

*(t) = (e(A-P/)(T-t) - j) (A - pi)-1 e,

R (t) = min

sn=i(bj aj (t))2

4(1+ pi )2

; r (M.

4. The Stackelberg Game of the Principal with the Influence Agents

Let us move to the principal's problem (l)-(2),(5)-(6). The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation has the form

v dVo pVo--— = max

dt ri(i),1<i<m

5>j (t) ri(t)

. j=1

i=1

^ dxo j=1 J

uk (t)^E a'j xi

k=1

i=1

with conditions 0 <Y1 !=1 ri(t) < R, ri(t) > 0 , i = 1, 2,..., m , where

. , vbjaj(t))2 ri(t)(bjaj(

uj (t) = mm ' —-•---

_ (bj aj (t))2 rj (t)(bj aj (t))2

'4(1+ Pi)2 ^"=1 (bjaj(t))2

The equation (16) takes the form:

(16)

pVo - no=ri(tjrnax<m ^ x(t) ^ ri(t) +^ ■

j=1

i=1

j=1

dxo

Ea'j xi +

J=1

bij

bj aj (t)|

" ' Vj (bjaj (t)) 2 '

Let us take the linear Bellman function

■¿(bj aj (t))2 ;v/T~M

j=1

.

Vo (x,t) =53 a0 (t)xj + ^0(t). j=1

Let us show that a0(t) = aj(t), j = 1, 2, ...,n , t G [0, T] . Equating in (17) the

xj

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

differential equation for a0(t):

0(t) - pa°(t)^ a0(t)aji = -1,

i=1

1

which coincides with (10) for the same boundary conditions

a(T ) = 0,

therefore

a0(t) = a] (t) = ... = j(t) = aj(t), j = 1, 2, ...,n,t G [0; T]. (18)

Let us call a0(t) the opinion value of the j-th basic agent for the principal. In the principal's Bellman function V0(x,t) = En=1 a°(t)x¿ + ß0 (t) the fact or a0(t) is the weight coefficient of the opinion of the respective basic agent. Thus, from the condition (18) we receive

Proposition 2. Tfte opinion value of each basic agent is the same for all influence agents and the principal.

With consideration of (18) we can rewrite (17) as

p iß0 + ¿axjj - iß'0 + ¿ajxjj =

= max

(t) ri (t)+EE aj (t)aijxi +

I j=1 i=1 i=1 j=1

+S S jj{râ

If the minimum is attained in the first expression, the function decreases on r-j(t), and the optimal value of r-j(t) is minimal. It is minimal if the expressions under the sign of minimum are equal. Thus, the minimum is attained in the second expression or it is absent.

Notice that the non-conditional maximization of the expression (19) gives the amount of resources

1 "

ri(t) = jE «j (*))2 • j=1

In this case

(t) = mm (bj (t))2 ; ^^ = (bj «j(t))2 •

It means that it is not advantageous for the principal to allocate the amount of resources

1 n

r<(t) = lE (bjaj(t))2 .

4 j=i

Thus, the principal allocates to an influence agent as many resources as the latter is ready to assign for the common purposes, i.e.

ri (t) = 4(TT^ ¿ $ajW)2 . (2°)

and we receive the following

Proposition 3. The influence agents assign less resources for the marketing efforts than the principal would like.

Thus if

V jj! — 4R ¿Í <1+ pi)2 "

then the principal allocates to each agent the amount of resources equal to (20).

How the principal should allocate the resources if 3=(11+pQ)'2(t)) > 4R? The

answer is given by the conditional maximization of the expression (19). Maximizing the right hand side of (19) by r^t), i = 1, 2,..., m with condition ri(t) — R, we receive

r,(t) = R g-i('*"»S>2 2.

w K-,E n-i (a (f)b')2

Thus, in the instants t e [0, T] when

V E? , j — 4R,

i=i (1+ Pi)2

the optimal control of the principal is

1 "

ri(t) = 4(1+Pi)2 E (bj "j (t)) 2 ' i = 1' 2 ...' m'

and in the instants t e [0, T] when

V j j > 4R,

= (1+Pi)2 the optimal control of the principal is

ri(t)= j<jt)bj)2 2 R,i = 1, 2, ..., m. £"ilj-i ("j(tj2 ' " '

Combining both expressions for ri (t) in the same formula, we receive the final optimal control of the principal:

ri (t) = j(aj(t)bj) 2 2 min Í 1 V V (t)bk )2 ; R l , (21)

() X"-i j ("j (tj2 \ 4(1+ Pi)2 ¿Íj-T J() j ' J' 1 '

i = 1, 2,..., m, t e [0,T],

where

a(t) = (e(A-P/)(T-t) - j) (A - p/)-ie.

Given (21) we can simplify (19) because

1 ™ £" (bj(t))

2

and the last term in (19) is

(a (t)bj)2

EE

1 j (aj(t)bj)2 I 2(1 +

(i)bj)2

j=i

2 i=1 1+pi , (1+Pi)2 - 4R'

Vr Em=i e;= (bj ay (t))2, Em=1E > 4R.

Equating the constant terms in the left and right hand sides of (19), we receive the differential equation for ,00(t) :

£'0(t) - p^0(t) = f (t), (22)

where

f (t) = i 4 ei=1 e;=1 (bj a(j (t))2 , ET=1 E^py))2 - 4R

l Em=1 E;=1 (bjay(t))2 - r, Em=1E^pff)r > 4R.

Solving the equation (22) by the method of variation of parameters, we receive:

cT

it

When t = 0 we have

t-T

ß0 (t) = J e-p(T-t)f (t )dr.

ß0(0) = / e-pT f (t )dT. 0

0

Thus, the maximal guaranteed payoff of the principal is

max J0 = V0(x(0), 0) = V ay(0)xy(0) + / e-pTf (t)dr, (24)

r»,1<i<m ' ^ In

1 j=1 0

where the components ay (0), j = 1,2,..., n of the vector a(0) are determined by the expression (12), and f (t) is determined by the expression (23).

5. System Compatibility Index

Now let us calculate the system compatibility index:

SCJ - maX-(t> min"j WeNB(r.W) J0 ({ri}m=1 i {{uj {xj }"=1)

maxri(t) max„j (t) J0({ri }m=1, {{uj }n=1 }m=1, {x }n=1) '

where the set NE (rj(t)) is the Nash equillibrium of the agents of influence in re-sponce to the resource amount r (t).

This index shows the measure of compatability of system. The numerator of (25) is the payoff of the principal in the case if the firms choose the most unfavorable for principal equilibrium strategies. The denumerator of (25) is the payoff of the principal in the case if the firms choose the most favorable for principal strategies. It is evident that 0 < SCI < 1. A similar formula is used in the paper (Agieva, Korolev and Ougolnitsky, 2019).

In our case the set of equilibrium strategies of each influence agent given the principal's strategy is a singleton, therefore, the numerator in (25) is equal to the right hand side of the formula (24).

For the calculation of the denominator in the expression (25) let us assume that each influence agent maximizes not his payoff but the principal's payoff given her strategy, i.e. the influence agent solves the problem

/T n

X ^ max,

j=i

with conditions (4)-(6). This function is introduced for finding the influence agent stratigies which maximize the payoff function of the Centre.

The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation has the form

T, dVi " " dVj

PV--— = max < > x3(t) + > ——

H dt u,i<j<n | ^ j ( ) + ^ dx,-

j' <j< I o=i o=i 3

uk (t) + E

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

ay X;

k=1

;=i

(26)

with condition 0 < En=i uj(t) < ^¿(t)- Maximization by uj, j = 1, 2,..., n, bj = 0,

we receive

a dV.

3 dx,

I b dV. ¿^3=i \ 3 dx,

and, naturally,

]Tu3 (t) = R (t).

3=i

Taking the linear Bellman functions

V (x,t) = E aj (t)xj + fti(t),

3=i

(27)

we can write the equation (26) with consideration of (27) as

p5>3 (t)xj + P^i (t) - E aji (t)xj - (t)

3=i 3=I

E Xj W + EE aj (t)aij x; + EE aj W j

3=i l=i 3=I k=i j=i (ai (t)6k)'

2

x

a

aj(t) - paj(t)+¿ aj(t)aJ-í = -1,

(29)

;=i

coinciding with the equations (10) solved by the expression (12).

Choosing the maximal value of the right hand side of (28) in dependence on the sum of R (t), we have

R(t) = ri(t),

that is natural because the influence agents care for the principal's payoff instead of their own one. Thus, the strategies of all influence agents are:

uj (t)

Ti(t) (bjq3- (t))2 £"=i (bjaj(t))2

(30)

and, therefore,

EU (t)= ri (t), j=1

where aj (t), j = 1, 2,..., n are the components of the vector a(t) which is determined by the expression (12).

Let us move to the principal's problem (l)-(2),(5). The condition (5) with consideration of (30) can be immediately written as

x j = E bj

aj (t)bj

E

i=1 V^n=1 (aj (t)bj)2 i=1

The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation has the form

ay x;.

v dVo

pVo--— = max % i xo

dt r¿(t),1<i<m I ^^ . j=1

^x,- (t) -J2 Ti(t) +

E

j=i

dxo-

Ev^i bj

i=1

V j (aj(t)bj)

Ea'j x'(t)

;=i

with condition Ei=1 ri(t) — R r,(t) > 0 i = 1, 2,..., m. Let us use the linear Bellman function:

n

V0(x,t) = ^ a°°(t)xj + £0(t), j=1

then the equation (31) takes the form

(31)

P Iß0 + E a°°Xj I - Iß'0 + E aj0x

j=i

j=i

max < >^Xo (t) —

r¿(t),i<i<m I ^^ j=i

-E Ti (t) + E<

¿=i

j=i

m (+\hi n

E V/Ti^bj aj ( ) j + £ ayx; (t)

i=i

Vj (aj(t)bj)2 ;=i

(32)

2

0

j

with condition Emi r»(t) — R r(t) > 0 i = 1, 2,..., m.

Let us show that a0(t) = aj(t), j = 1, 2, ...,n, t G T. Equating in (32) the

coefficients at the first power of xj in the left and right hand sides, we receive the j(tV

differential equation for a0(t):

aj0(t) - pa0(t) + X a0(t)a,7 = -1,

;=i

which coincides with (10) for the same boundary conditions

a(T) = 0,

therefore

a0(t) = ai(t) = ... = am(t) = aj(t), j = 1, 2,...,n,t G [0; T]. (33)

With consideration of (33) we can rewrite (32) as

p | ft0 + E ajxj I - I ft'0 + ]T ajxj I = m^ ^ Xj (t) - ^ r(t)+

(t)ayx + E ^

j=il=i i=i

]T(aj(t)bj)234)

j=i

with condition ri(t) < R ri(t) > 0 i = 1,2, ...,m. Notice that the non-conditional maximization of the expression (34) gives the value of resources

1 n

ri(t) = ^E (bjajW)2 . (35)

j=i

Thus, the principal is interested to allocate to each influence agent i the value of resources (35). Therefore if

m n

EE(bjajW)2 < 4R,

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

i=ij=i

then the principal allocates to each influence agent i the value of resources (35). How the principal should allocate the resources if Em=i En=i (bj a j(t)) > 4R? Maximizing the right hand side of (34) by ri(t), i = 1, 2,..., m with condition Em^ r (t) < R> we receive

En 1 (a7- (t)b!- )2 ri(t) = R Z^3=i 1 j( ) ^-2.

Er=iE n=i (aj (t)bj)2

Thus, in the instants t G [0, T] when

.. m n

R ^ I EE (bjaj(t))2

i=i j=i

the principal's optimal control value is

ri(i) = z£ (bj a (t))2 •

j=i

In the instants t G [0,T] when

-, m n

R< jEE (bj " W) 2 .

i=i j=i

the principal's optimal control value is

ri (t)

j (gj(t)bj)2

EHiEn=i (" (t)bj)

2ñ, i = 1, 2, ..., m.

Combining both expressions for ri(t) in the same formula, we receive the final principal's optimal control:

ri (t)

En=i (oj(t)frj)2

Em=i e;=I (aj (t)bk )

min { zEE ("j (tj2 ; ñ

k=i j=i i = 1, 2,m, t G [0,T],

where

«(t) = (e(A-P/)(T- j) (A - p/)-ie.

Given (36) we can simplify (34) because

(36)

Eri(t) = min { (bj"j(t))2

i=i

i=i j=i

and the last term in (34) is equal to

m

E

i=i

\

E("j (t)bj)

j=i

\

k=ij=i

\

£!>, (')bj) .

k=ij=i

Equating the constant terms in the left and right hand sides of (34), we receive the differential equation for ft0(t):

ß'0(t) - pß0(t) = V(t),

(37)

where

m n

V(t) = min{ ^EEj(t))2;

k=ij=i

^EEX "j W)2 - ñ, (38) k=i j=i

2

i.e.

IEI=iEn=i (j«J(*))2 , EI=1 E^i (ja,(t))2 < 4R, VRËÎÏj^bjf - R, El^ E;=i (bj a, (t))2 > 4R.

Thus, the equation (37) coincides with the equation (22) for the same boundary-conditions, therefore,

When t = 0 we have

'(t) = J e-p(T-t)^(T)dT.

£0(0) = i e-pT^(t)dT, 0

where ^(t) is determined by the expression (37).

Thus, the denominator of the expression (25) maxyeY maxzeZ J0(y, z), or the global maximum of the principal's payoff in the case of cooperative behavior, is equal to:

n T

VV- (0)xj- (0)+ / e-pT ^(t )dT, j=1 J0

where aj(0^ j = 1,2,..., n , ^re determined by the formula (12), and ^(t) is determined by the expression (37).

The system compatibility index in this problem is equal to

SCI = En=1 aj (0)xj (0) + /0T e-pTf (t)dT < 1 En=1 aj (0)xj (0) + /0T e-pT^(t'

Notice that the complete system compatibility is achieved only if f (t) = ^(t), ()

Em=1 En=1 (bjaj (t^ — 4R(1+pj)2 is true, and they lack resources for the common purpose.

6. Conclusion

We considered a dynamic SPICE-model of resource allocation in a marketing network. The network includes a coordinating principal that allocates resources, several influence agents (competing firms), and basic agents which form the target audience. The model represents a differential Stackelberg game of the principal with the influence agents. In the case of linear functions of private income of the influence agents we found analytically the unique Nash equilibrium in the game of agents and Stackelberg equilibrium in the general game by means of the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equations. We proved that the opinion value of any basic agent is equal for all influence agents and the principal. Also we proved that the influence agents assign less resources for the marketing efforts than the principal would like.

We plan to spread the received results to the functions of private income in more general form. Besides, it seems rational to consider in more details the firm's utility from buying by the basic agents the goods and services of this specific firm instead of all firms in the totality.

References

Agieva, M.T., A.V. Korolev and G. A. Ougolnitsky (2019). Modeling and Simulation of Impact and Control in Social Networks. In: Modelling and Simulation of Social-Behavioural Phenomena in Creative Societies: First International EURO Mini Conference, MSBC 2019. Vilnius, Lithuania, September 18-20, 2019 Proceedings. Communications in Computer and Information Science (Agarwal, N., L. Sakalauskas and G.-W. Weber, eds), Vol. 1079, pp. 29-40.

Anopchenko, T., O. Gorbaneva, E. Lazareva, A. Murzin and G. Ougolnitsky (2019a). Advanced Solow model as a tool for coordination of interests of spatial economic systems' development (on the materials of the South Russian macro-region). Advances in Systems Science and Applications, 19(4), 1-13.

Anopchenko, T., O. Gorbaneva, E. Lazareva, A. Murzin, G. Ougolnitsky and E. Roshchina (2019b). Dynamic Model of Macroregion Subjects' Interests Coordination. In: Proceedings - 2019 1st International Conference on Control Systems, Mathematical Modelling, Automation and Energy Efficiency, SUMMA 2019, art. no. 8947516, pp. 141-146.

Chkhartishvili, A., D. Gubanov and D. Novikov (2019). Social Networks: Models of Information Influence, Control, and Confrontation. Springer Publishers.

Gorbaneva, O.I. (2019). Models of social and private interests combining with independent agents. Automation and Remote Control, 80(9), 1745-1753.

Jackson, M. (2008). Social and Economic Networks. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Long, N. V. (2010). A Survey of Dynamic Games in Economics. World Scientific Publishing Company.

Nisan, N., T. Roughgarden, E. Tardos and V. Vazirani (2007). Algorithmic Game Theory. Cambridge University Press.

Sedakov A. A. and M. Zhen (2019). Opinion dynamics game in a social network with two influence nodes. Applied Mathematics. Computer Science. Control Processes, 15(1), 118-125.

Sukhinov A.I., G. A. Ougolnitsky and A.B. Usov (2020). Methods of Solving the Theoretic Game Models for Coordinating Interests in Regulating the Fishery Industry. Mathematical Models and Computer Simulations, 12(2), 176-184.

Ugol'nitskii G. A. and A.B. Usov (2020). Dynamic Models for Coordinating Private and Public Interests in Economic Corruption. Journal of Computer and Systems Sciences International, 59(1), 39-48.

Zhen, M. (2019). Stackelberg equilibrium in opinion dynamics game in social network with two influence nodes. In: Contributions to Game Theory and Management. Vol. XII. Collected Papers of the Twelfth International Conference "Game Theory and Management" (Petrosyan, L. and N. Zenkevich, eds), St. Petersburg: Saint Petersburg State University, pp. 29-40.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.