Научная статья на тему 'Assessment of forest rent in the Russian economy'

Assessment of forest rent in the Russian economy Текст научной статьи по специальности «Сельское хозяйство, лесное хозяйство, рыбное хозяйство»

CC BY
71
12
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
Ключевые слова
ТЕОРИЯ РЕНТЫ / ЛЕСНОЙ КОМПЛЕКС / ПРИРОДОПОЛЬЗОВАНИЕ / ЛЕСНАЯ РЕНТА / THEORY OF RENT / FOREST COMPLEX / NATURAL RESOURCE USE / FOREST RENT

Аннотация научной статьи по сельскому хозяйству, лесному хозяйству, рыбному хозяйству, автор научной работы — Pyzhev Anton I., Zander Evgeniya V., Pyzheva Yulia I.

The aim of the paper is to give the overview of the best available techniques of forest rent assessment. First of all, we study the common theory of rent considering both “classical” and “Paretian” approac h to the definition of rent. Examining the forest rent evaluation experience of Russian authors, we state that they are based on the “Paretian” approach to the rent definition and don’t use the “classical” definition. However, the “Paretian” rent is much more exigent than the “classical” one, and this fact could explain why there are no modern and comprehensive studies of the forest rent for the Russian economy.

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.
iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.
i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.

Текст научной работы на тему «Assessment of forest rent in the Russian economy»

Journal of Siberian Federal University. Humanities & Social Sciences 8 (2013 6) 1240-1248

y^K 332.68

Assessment of Forest Rent in the Russian Economy

Anton I. Pyzhev*, Evgeniya V. Zander and Yulia I. Pyzheva

Siberian Federal University 79 Svobodny, Krasnoyarsk, 660041 Russia

Received 25.07.2013, received in revised form 01.08.2013, accepted 08.08.2013

The aim of the paper is to give the overview of the best available techniques offorest rent assessment. First of all, we study the common theory of rent considering both "classical" and "Paretian " approach to the definition of rent. Examining the forest rent evaluation experience of Russian authors, we state that they are based on the "Paretian" approach to the rent definition and don't use the "classical" definition. However, the "Paretian" rent is much more exigent than the "classical" one, and this fact could explain why there are no modern and comprehensive studies of the forest rent for the Russian economy.

Keywords: theory of rent, forest complex, natural resource use, forest rent

The publication was prepared within the framework of the project no. 13-02-00186 supported by the Russian Foundation for Humanities.

1. Introduction

It is common knowledge that the economy of Russia is based upon the extraction of natural resource, mainly intended for export as raw materials and products of low technological conversions. The inferior technological level of the Russian industry underlines the exceptional importance of forest complex's problems' studying using the most advanced modern approaches.

Forest products remain one of the most important export items in the Russian trade balance, along with oil and gas that fill up to 50 % of the country's budget. According to the assessment of the Food and Agricultural Organisation of the United Nations (FAO),

the total area of the forestlands in Russia was approximately 882 million hectares in 2010, and the overall stock of forest was 82 billion cubic metres (FAO, 2012). This implies that Russia possesses the largest stock of forest resources in the world. The problem is that only a small share of such a great potential is currently being used in mid- and long-run perspective. The first reason of such a poor state of the Russian forest complex is the impossibility of access to the main part of forestlands situated in little-developed areas with severe climate conditions. The second reason is the bad quality of forest management (Eikeland et al., 2004).

Despite the fact that there is a vast literature dedicated to the assessment of oil and gas

© Siberian Federal University. All rights reserved

* Corresponding author E-mail address: apyzhev@sfu-kras.ru

rent (Gaddy, Ickes, 2005; Gol'denberg, 2006; Gurvich, 2010; Guriev et al., 2010), the forest rent is discussed much less often. In the presented paper we try to give a review of the existing approaches to the assessment of forest rent and the accumulated experience of evaluating of the Russian forest's rent.

2. Theory of Rent

It is quite important to strictly define the term of rent prior to talk about forest rent. Let us refer to the classical modern textbook on microeconomics of P. Samuelson and W. Nordhaus (2003): "The rent is the payment for using the factors of production whose supply is fixed".

It is evaluated as the amount of money paid in a time unit (Samuelson, Nordhaus, 2003: 470). Thus, the natural rent is the payment for natural resource use paid in a time unit, for example, for one month, to the owner of production factor "natural resource".

The definition of rent expressed above sounds pretty simple and clear, nevertheless several questions arise, if one makes an attempt to evaluate the rent using this definition. Does the rent include resource reproduction costs? Is it possible to treat the rent as a fixed income of the resource's owner, independent of resource's income? What is primary: the product's price defines the rent or vice versa? These issues were in the main focus of study for the most prominent scholars of the past since "A Treatise of Taxes and Contributions" of W. Petty (1662) through the "Cours d'Économie Politique Professé a l'Université de Lausanne" of V. Pareto (1896). It is amazing to know that there was almost no significant contribution to the theory of rent in the 20th century. However, one needs to mention a well-known study of D. Worchester (1946) which contains a brilliant review of the main achievements of the theory of rent

during XVIII-XIX centuries. It is important not to forget a series of publication on so-called Sraffa's theory of rent (Sraffa, 1960), despite that it is not a purely new theory, because it is based on Ricardian definition of rent.

According to Worchester (1946), one should distinguish among three schools of rent theory: representatives of classical political economy ("classics"), neoclassical economic theory ("neoclassics"), and successors of famous Italian mathematician, statistic and economist V. Pareto ("Paretians"). Since the neoclassical school has no made significant contribution into the theory of A. Marshall (1890), except the transition from residual approach to the marginal, the visions of its representatives could be merged into one school together with "classics" (Worchester, 1946). Thus, it is worthwhile to consider two main approaches: classical and Paretian.

Classical approach to the definition of the rent suggests treating it as a remainder that yields from subtraction of capital and labour costs from the final price of the product. A proof of this statement may be found in (Worchester, 1946: 260). One way or the other, this point-of-view is shared by A. Smith, D. Ricardo and A. Marshall. Actually, this definition is equivalent to the "marginal".

V. Pareto defines the rent as the return for any agent of production greater than that required to keep it in its present employment (cited according to Worchester, 1946: 261). In other words, for Pareto and his successors the rent is the surplus appropriated by the owner of resource as a payment for its uniqueness. Meanwhile, this approach to the rent definition makes practical evaluation of the rent pretty difficult, because it is hard to extract the "normal" income that holds the possessor of the resource. It is possible if one introduce some conventional level, which would be connected to the real one only hypothetically.

3. Experience of Evaluating of the Forest Rent

As was mentioned in (Eismont et al., 2002), in highly developed countries the technique of forest rent evaluating described below is widespread. The value of the rent is calculated as the difference between market price on round wood and the cost of production including normal level of profitability. This approach supposes that there is a reliable system of accounting. It is also important to strictly follow the technique, which may be quite detailed and complex. For example, one of the Forest Service Handbooks of the US Forest Agency dedicated to the evaluation of timber standing price in the Pacific North-West consists of more than 300 pages. Unfortunately, this approach is not applicable in Russia, due to opacity of accounting and statistics in forest industry and complexity of the methodology

It is also valuable to consider the experience of the Australian island state Tasmania, where the indices for six parameters of the fixed forest area are calculated in order to assess the forest rent. The six indices are: (1) the overall available forest stock (subdivided into five classes); (2) access to the market defined as the distance of transportation (three classes); (3) climate (three classes); (4) forest quality (three classes); (5) distance to the wood processing plant (five classes); (6) topography and soil quality (three classes).

The Russian experience ascends to "The Directions for taxes evaluating for forest materials received from state dachas" (1883) based on rent theory framework. This document suggested evaluating the price of standing timber as a remainder price, or forest rent, i.e. the difference between market price of forest materials and the cost of stocking up and transportation including the profit of timber merchant.

4. Institutional Environment of the Russian Forest Sector

The forest legislation in Russia is based on the Forest Code of the Russian Federation (FC RF, 2006), which regulates the relations arising regarding the usage of forest resources. According to the part 1, article 8 of FC RF, forestland areas belong to the Russian Federation. So, there is no private ownership on forestlands in Russia.

The forest resources in Russia fully belongs to the State, so all the timber merchants use the forest lands and the resources situated on them according to the principle of payment for the forest (part 1, article 1 and 94 FC RF).

The calculation technique for the rental payment for forest resources is defined by article 73 FC RF. According to the part 2, article 73 FC RF, if a forest area is exploited in an effort to commercially extract forest resources, the minimal rental payment is defined as a rate for the unit of forest resources multiplied by the area of the forestland to be rented (part 3, article 73 FC RF). If the usage of a forestland doesn't suppose the extraction of forest resources, then the minimal rental payment is defined as a rate for the unit of forestland area multiplied by the area of the forestland to be rented (part 3, article 73 FC RF). These rates are stated by the Government of the Russian Federation, regional and local authorities (part 4, article 73 FC RF).

Article 76 FC RF determines the value of payment for the purchase of forest standings in commercial objectives. The minimal rental payment for the forest standings could be defined as the product of a rate for one unit of timber and the volume of the wood to be lumbered (part 2, article 73 LC RF). These rates are stated by the Government of the Russian Federation, regional and local authorities (part 3, article 73 FC RF).

The acting rates of payments for the unit of forest resources volume and for the unit of area of a forestland area belonging to the Russian

Federation are approved by the resolution of the Government of the Russian Federation No. 310 dated May 27, 2007. These rates are defined accurate within species of forest standings, tax classes, distances of transportation, category of timber. Every year the Government approves step-up coefficients for these rates.

Part 1, article 95 FC RF states that the evaluation of forests is conducted according to the Federal Law No. 135-FZ dated July 29, 1998 "On the evaluative activity in the Russian Federation", i.e. the Forest Code doesn't contain any specific techniques for evaluating0 of forest resources.

5. Evaluation of the Forest Rent in Russia

In spite of the fact that there are a some dozens of Russian scholars who develop the issues of the forest rent assessment, these wotks are mostly theoretical, meanwhile there is no statistically approved results in this do main. The rare exceptions from this rule; are the studies (Pochinkov, 2010a, 2010b; Eismont et al., 2002).

In the works of S. Pochinkov (2 010a, 2010b) the forest rent is supposed to be the remainder price, the result of subtraction of socially esaential costs spent on production and consumption of forest products from its final market price. In other words, authors use the classical approach to the rent definition. The forest rent and the net income of usage and consumption of forest stands for main use cut could be evaluated at different stages of getting and selling of the forest production: (1) processing of tire timber into the final product; (2) lumbering and selling of round wood materials; (3) selling of standing wood.

At the stage of processing of timber into the production of final consumption forest rent r could be evaluated as:

where P0 denotes matket price of one production unit of round wood and its materials (carving wood, pulp, paper, plywood etc.) in the departure station;

Ct ate tht cuttent costs on timber procesting excluding the coct of raw wood including the costs on returning of main assets and interests on credrt;

K0 are the tpecific capital inveatments in processing production (buildings, structutes, equipment etc;.);

s is the raw wood expenditure related to one unit of the wood processing product;

10 is the profit rate on the main and circulating capital in wood processing;

Cj are ihe current: exptnditures on wood otocking up and its transportation from the forest to the "low" warehouse, selling poinr or the processing pfani, rncluding rhe ooofs on oetutning of main assets und interesft on ceedit; K is the main and circulating capital used in lumbering, including specific capital investments into removar of logs and constructing of the food st transportation roads;

11 is the profit rate on the main and circulating capital used in lumbering.

Ai Che stoge of sellmg of round wood the forest rent could be calculated as:

r = P1-r1- i1K1,

where Pi denotes iho market price of ong unit oi round wood af the; departure station, C1, K1, i1 are the same parameters as in the formula written above. Thio formula could tie applied if the rights on usage of the forertlandt areas are pnovkled Co the timber merchants, whose produofion is being sel1 on the known markets with transparent prices.

At the stage of selling of the standing wood, forest rent r may be defines as:

r = rm,

where rm denotes the payment for standing wood, defined on auctions for analogous forestland. This approach is suitable for the cases when the most part of forest area is a subject of selling on the forest auction.

The particular interest should be focused on the study of O. Eismont et al. (2002). The authors analyse the application of two approaches to the assessment of forest rent: (1) excluding of all the costs from market price of forest (according to the widespread definition of rent), (2) econometrical evaluation of the forest rent based on the data from forest auctions.

In the first case the cash flow method and evaluating of net present value (NPV) method are applicable. The normal profit is treated as the cash flow yielding by some asset. This method corresponds to the Current Rent Method I of The Bureau of Economic Analysis of the USA. The dataset of Research and Design Institute of Economics, Production Management and Information for Forest, Pulp and Paper and Woodworking Industries (NIPIEIlesprom, dataset No. 1) and data from regional Agencies of Forest Complex retrieved in 1998 (dataset No. 2) were used as the input data.

When calculating the rent according to the method of cash flow, the normal profit is supposed to be a cash of incomes returned by some asset. Data on incomes is contained only in dataset No. 1, and these incomes include prices "Free on Board" (FOB) and "Cost, Insurance and Freight" (CIF). Prices CIF are used to evaluate the revenue.

In the dataset No. 2 process costs are evaluated as the difference between the costs of lumbering for the forest located on the "low" warehouse and

the standing wood price. In the dataset No. 1 the costs are defined the same way. In the dataset No. 2 the sales expenses are defined as a sum of costs of lumbering for the forest located on the "low" warehouse, transport fees and the cost of loading. Then, the authors calculate the expected gross profit, which could be evaluated using the data on revenue and costs: expected gross profit = revenue - costs. It is possible to evaluate the expected volume of taxes using the data from dataset No. 2: expected taxes volume = expected gross value x 30 % (if the gross value is positive) + standing wood price + export fees. When calculating using dataset No. 1, standing wood price is included into process costs and could not be extracted. All the other taxes including social insurance deductions are accounted in each dataset as a part of process costs. The value of standard income returned by the corresponding asset was assessed for the evaluation of normal profit for the whole forest sector (Eismont, 2002).

In the cited study the evaluation of forest rent for eight Russian regions and for the whole Russia was held (Arkhangelsk, Leningrad, Moscow, Novgorod, Pskov, Vologda Oblasts, Khabarovsk and Krasnoyarsk Krai). While estimating, there was stated that the data from both datasets are quite unreliable and could significantly vary depending on the primary source of the data. That's why Eismont et al. have made the conclusion that this approach is almost inapplicable in the Russian conditions.

The second approach supposes the econometrical modeling of the forest rent considering the following rent-producing factors: timber volume, transportation distance, soil type, site slope, forest type.

The authors of the opus citatum proceed from the assumption that the timber merchant acquires the right for usage of the forestland area total square of A hectares. The area to be cut

down during one yeat could be describedwith a production function:

Y = F(K,L,A, Q,d),

dQ '3d

where K denotes capital being used, L is the number of workers, Q is the timber volume, d is the distance belween the lumbering point and the railroad station or highway.

Omitting further computations, we give the final formula for the forest rent according to the model:

where denotes the market price of the wood excluding transportation costs (railroad or highway); is the costs of stock usage including depreciation and normal profit; is the overall salary of workers; is the total value of capital used for lumbering counting on hectare; is the wood volume in cubic meters counting on hectare; is the depreciation rate accounted in the total costs.

Then the authors have conducted the forest rent evaluation using normative data on the productivity of the manual labor and machines and mechanisms. The econometrical models were estimated for the three different lumbering technologies using the data from Komi Republic in 1997. It was proved that the largest rent is returned by the technology that uses manual labor force and machines and mechanisms of non-Russian production. Mixed sets of equipment (both Russian and non-Russian) demonstrate minor results (Eismont, 2002: 35). In general, according to the data provided by lumberers, their productions were unprofitable, the rent was negative. It is likely that this statement is contrary to fact, because some part of the forest is excluded

from the offic ial statistics and accounting and is selling using illegal ways.

Besides the forest rent assessment based on normative data, authors also used the information from the forest auctions trading the rights on lumbering (as an example dataset they used the reeults ot such auctions in Novgorod Oblast in 1999).

The results of calculations showed that the average market price for timber are one and half times more than the auction ones, and the costs of lumbering estimated with the auction prices, are two times less than those which were calculated with the normative data. It occurs because of monopsony established on the forest production market, where there are a lot of timber merchants and a short list of consumers of the timber. The merchants are forced to sell their wood approximately up to 30 % cheaper than market price. This surplus, which includes, for sure, the forest rent, is appropriated by intermediates who don't really participate in the production process and don't possess any resources. So, legally they don't have any rights on this rent (Eismont et al., 2002: 47).

The results of the complex macro economical assessment of rental incomes in Russia in the beginning of 2000-s are presented in (Kuzyk et al., 2004; Volkonskiy et al., 2010). According to the method, set forth in the studies mentioned above, the evaluation of the rental income value represent the comparison of the income gained by the branches of natural resource use and the value of a mean income among other branches. Thus, actually this study implicitly uses the Paretian definition of the rent.

Kuzyk et al. mention that the rental income must be computed on the primary income before taxes. This restriction arise because the Russian tax legislation doesn't stipulate for attachment of the rent as a tax, so from the point-of-view of taxation the owner of mineral deposits doesn't

differ from the owner of any other capital in other sector of economy. Since the Fedaraf Law "On subsoils" rCates that all the minerals dispoeed on the territoey of the Russian Federation are the property of the Srare, and only the activity connected! with the usage of factoor of production noi belongtng to the State could be taxed, the rental income is not ohe tax. Genertlly spoken, it could be extrartsd only from the primnry cinc ome setutned ftom ohe sellingof hett-producing naturaC resources.

The authort suggest such t lisfof the; ppi"odiic;inir branches of thcRusstan economy: (fil and gar producOion, Oetrour and non-fesraus metallucgy. The rent income to be retufned by ^hie; sent-pfoduaing ttranches can In e computed as a difference between the primary income and the nfrmrtivr income of any used oesources excluding natural:

e ^ h - is

wheat Ih dejnotejsi jtr-intcriro^ income oO the branch, and jf* lllSIto"t ear ^h<e norm^tivo income ci^cnu^^nedt foe this specific branch.

The normative income /¿* could be defined through the mean profitability telated to the current costs or the value of main asyets of national economy (or its manufactuoing industry only):

/* = KcCi, 1* = KpF".

Here KC and KF are the mean profitability related to the current costs and ohe value of main assets, respectively; C are thc process costs in the i-th branch; Ioi is the value of main assets used for production in the i-t= branch.

Then, the authors of the technique calculate the base coefficients of prime cost for all the main bcanches cf natural resource use. Using tgese coefficient one could ralculate the total

national (or regional) rental ineome wioh a stmple fofmhla:

R = briVi, i

wgone je ddtteno-teas; the volume of production in the i-th branch of economy, g is the share of rental income iy the total ppoduction of i-th branch.

The shares on eental income in rhe mrin r^n^t-j)roducinii^ bdoncnes of the Russian iIrdnstyy woseestimated in (Ryumina, Anikina, 2007: 165): oil iindu^t]iy-:58,4 %, gas industry-61,9 %, ^eti-illifrg^-:::^,^ %. However, since 2005 the application off ahese estimates is not possible any mote, because rhe Russian sy stem si of statistics migrated from the old soviet system (the AllUnion Nomenclature of Sectors of the Naiional Economy, OKONKh) to the modern cine (the All-Rustian Clgtiifier of Types of Ecrnoniiic Acliv ity, OKVED). These sy stems have totally different internal structures of keys, so the application ot this rechmque would be possible only when is is adapted no she new statistical tehnodnlogy OKVED.

Despite that ihe foreh branch io not the part of main yoht-producinn branches of the Russian economy, the authors have evaluated the Ootest rent in 2000-2001 according to their methodology (Kuzyk et hl., 2004!: 98-103). In thae perio d, the branch collected the main revenut ftom the export (approx. 55 % of the overall revenue). The same situation holds out to present dsy. Accordioa to the results of assessment, the rental income was about 30 %> of the whole revenue (the producer's prices were used for estimation). Meanwhile, the authors state that approximately 25-30 % of the final price is appropriated by the different intermediates, and not the State or the owner of resources. This eonclusion corresponds to the conclusion oh Eismont et al. (2002).

6. Conclusion

Unfortunately, the assessment of the forest rent in Russia always face a specific obstacle, namely the existence of a significantly large shadow sector. By the assessment of the Federal Forestry Agency of the Russian Federation (Rosleskhoz), the volume of illegal cut of the forest in Russia in 2010 did not exceed 1 %. This would be a very optimistic situation fitting the best world standards, but there are some reasons to put it in doubt. For example, the World Bank (WB) and the World Wildlife Fund (WWF) evaluate the shadow sector of Russian forestry to be at least 20 % of the whole cut volume (16: xi-xii). Most likely, even such a huge estimate is moderate, so in fact much more forest cuts are "in shadow".

Thereby, in the presented study we traced the evolution of the rent theory in the economical science and stated that for the time being there are two main approaches to the definition of the

notion "rent". The "classical" approach suggests to think rent as a remainder produced by the subtraction of the labour and capital expense and the percent put on them from the final price of the product. The "Paretian" approach treats the rent as an excess over the normal income of the factor of production, i.e. the rent is the surplus appropriated by the owner of resource. During past decades the "Paretian" definition dominated in the rent theory. Particularly, the two most comprehensive and competent studies of the forest rent in the Russian economy made in early 2000s used exactly "Paretian" definition of the rent.

In our opinion, it would be interesting to get actualized estimates of the forest rent, especially for the period of the "rich" 2000s when the economy of Russia was growing by up 10 % each year. It is also important to remember that the definition of the rent have at least two purely different meanings, so one should evaluate the rent using both of them.

References

1. Eikeland, S., Eythorsson, E., Ivanova, L. From Management to Mediation: Local Forestry Management and the Forestry Crisis in Post-Socialist Russia (2004) Environmental Management, Vol. 33, 3, pp. 285-293.

2. Eismont, O. A., Petrov A. P., Logvin A. V., Boske B. D. Assessment of the forest rent and efficiency of the rental payments increase [Otsenka lesnoy renty I effektivnost' povysheniya rentnykh platezhey v Rossii]. Moscow, 2002.

3. FAO. The Russian Federation Forest Sector: Outlook Study to 2030. Rome: Food and Agricultural Organization of The United Nations, 2012.

4. Forest Code of the Russian Federation, 2006.

5. Gaddy, C. G., Ickes, B. W. Resource Rents and the Russian Economy (2005) Eurasian Geography and Economics, Vol. 46, 8, pp. 559-583.

6. Gol'denberg I. A. Natural resources valuation in the system of national accounts: Statistical calculation challenges and experience (2006) Studies on Russian Economic Development. Vol. 17, 5, pp. 481-489.

7. Guriev, S., Plekhanov A., Sonin K. Economical mechanism of the raw material development model [Ekonomicheskiy mekhanizm syryevoy modeli razvitiya] (2010) Voprosy ekonomiki, 3, pp. 4-23.

8. Gurvich, E. Oil- and gas-rent in the Russian economy [Neftegazovaya renta v rossiyskoy ekonomike] (2010) Voprosy ekonomiki, 2010, pp. 4-24.

iНе можете найти то, что вам нужно? Попробуйте сервис подбора литературы.

9. Kuzyk, B. N., Ageev A. I., Volkonskiy V. A., Kuzovkin A. I. Mudretsov A. F. Natural rent in the Russian economy [Prirodnaya renta v ekonomike Rossii]. Moscow, 2004.

10. Marshall, A. Principles of Economics, 1890.

11. Pareto, V. Cours d'Économie Politique Professé a l'Université de Lausanne, 1896.

12. Petty, W. A Treatise of Taxes and Contributions, 1662.

13. Pochinkov, S. The payment for standing wood [Plata za drevesinu na kornyu] (2010) Lesprominform,

3 (69), pp. 66-71.

14. Pochinkov, S. The payment for standing wood [Plata za drevesinu na kornyu] (2010) Lesprominform,

4 (70), pp. 82-89.

15. Ryumina, E. V., Anikina A. M. Analysis of the impact of natural resource factor on the level of economical development of Russia [Analiz vliyaniya faktora prirodnykh resursov na uroven' ekonomicheskogo razvitiya regionov Rossii] (2007) Problemy Prognozirovaniya, 5, pp. 106-125.

16. Samuelson, P. A., Nordhaus, W. D. Microeconomics, 18th Edition. McGraw-Hill, 2003.

17. The Directions for taxes evaluating for forest materials received from state dachas [Nastavleniya dlya sostavleniya taks na lesnyye materialy is kazennykh dach]. Saint-Petersburg, 1883.

18. Volkonskiy, V. A., Kuzovkin, A. I., Mudretsov, A. F. Natural rent and the methods for its assessment [Prirodnaya renta I metody yeyo otsenki] (2010) Problemy Prognozirovaniya, 1.

19. Worcester, D. A. Jr. A reconsideration of the theory of rent (1946) American Economic Review, Vol. 46, 3, pp. 248-257.

Оценка лесной ренты в экономике России

А.И. Пыжев, Е.В. Зандер, Ю.И. Пыжева

Сибирский федеральный университет Россия 660041, Красноярск, пр. Свободный, 79

Целью статьи является обзор способов оценки лесной ренты. Прежде всего мы рассматриваем общую теорию ренты, которая выделяет классическое и паретианское определения ренты. По результатам изучения отечественного опыта оценки лесной ренты можно сказать, что все они основываются на паретианском определении ренты и не используют классическое определение. Тем не менее, паретианское определение сушественно более требовательно, чем классическое. Это, по всей вероятности, объясняет тот факт, что на данный момент не существует актуальных крупномасштабных исследований, оценивающих лесную ренту в российской экономике.

Ключевые слова: теория ренты, лесной комплекс, природопользование, лесная рента

Публикация подготовлена в рамках поддержанного РГНФ научного проекта № 13-02-00186 «Эффективное управление рентой как источник долгосрочного развития лесного комплекса России».

i Надоели баннеры? Вы всегда можете отключить рекламу.