A Homoarchic Alternative to the Homoarchic State: Benin Kingdom of the 13th-19th Centuries*
Dmitri M. Bondarenko
Center for Civilization and Regional Studies, Moscow ABSTRACT
Until recently, cultural evolution has commonly been regarded as a permanent teleological move to a greater level of hierarchy, crowned with state formation. However, recent research based upon the principle of heterarchy - '... the relation of elements to one another when they are unranked or when they possess the potential for being ranked in a number of different ways' (Crumley 1995: 3) changes the usual picture dramatically. The opposite of heterarchy, then, would be a condition in a society in which relationships in most contexts are ordered mainly according to one principal hierarchical relationship. This organizational principle may be called 'homoarchy'. Homoarchy and heterarchy represent the most universal 'ideal' principles and basic trajectories of socio-cultural (including political) organization and its transformations. There are no universal evolutionary stages - band, tribe, chiefdom, state or otherwise - inasmuch as cultures so characterized could be heterarchical or homoarchical: they could be organized differently, while having an equal level of overall social complexity. However, alternativity exists not only between heterarchic and homo-archic cultures but also within each of the respective types.
In particular, the present article attempts at demonstrating that the Benin Kingdom of the 13th - 19th centuries, being an explicitly homoarchic culture not inferior to early states in the level of complexity, nevertheless was not a state as it lacked administrative specialization and pronounced priority of the supra-kin ties.
Social Evolution & History, Vol. 4 No. 2, September 2005 18-88 © 2005 'Uchitel' Publishing House
The Benin form of socio-political organization can be called 'megacommunity', and its structure can be depicted as four concentric circles forming an upset cone: the extended family, community, chiefdom, and megacommunity (kingdom). Thus, the homoarchic megacommunity turns out an alternative to the homoarchic by definition (Claessen and Skalnik 1978: 640) early state.
PREFACE: WHAT IS HOMOARCHY?
The word 'homoarchy' first came to the present author and his colleague, Andrey Korotayev's minds during an informal discussion of Carole Crumley's concept of 'heterarchy' (1979; 1987; 1995; 2001). Crumley (1995: 3; see also 1979: 144; 1987: 158; 2001: 25) defines the heterarchy '... as the relation of elements to one another when they are unranked or when they possess the potential for being ranked in a number of different ways', just in the vein heterarchy is defined in biophysics from which the term was imported by her to social science (see Crumley 1987: 156-157). Respectively, homoarchy may be coined as 'the relation of elements to one another when they are rigidly ranked one way only, and thus possess no (or at least very limited) potential for being unranked or ranked in another or a number of different ways at least without cardinal reshaping of the whole socio-political order'. The association used for delimitation of heterarchy and hierarchy in cybernetics is applicable for our purposes as well: 'Heterarchy [is the] form of organization resembling a network or fishnet' while 'Hierarchy [is the] form of organization resembling a pyramid' (Dictionary n.d).
However, in social science homoarchy must not be identified with hierarchy (as well as heterarchy must not be mixed up with egalitarianism [Brumfiel 1995: 129]). Hierarchy is an attribute of any social system while on the other hand, in any society both 'vertical' and 'horizontal' social links may be observed (Berreman 1981; Smith, M. E. 1985; Ehrenreich et al. 1995: 1-5, 87-100, 116-120, 125-131; Blanton 1998; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000c; for this dictum verity's explicit confirmation in recent works on an impressive variety of specific cultures, based on different kinds of sources - archaeological, written, and first-hand ethnographic, see e.g., Kelly 1993; Jolly and Mosko 1994; Small
1995; Wailes 1995; Kammerer 1998; Kristiansen 1998: 54-56; Nangoro 1998: 47-48; Anderson, C. E. 1999; Kuijt 2000: 312-315; Scarborough et al. 2003). More so: sometimes it seems too difficult to designate a society as 'homoarchic' or 'heterarchic' even at the most general level of analysis, like in the cases of the late-ancient Germans (see, e.g., Gurevich 1999: 45-57) and early-medieval 'Barbarian kingdoms' in which one can observe monarchy and quite rigid social hierarchy combined with (at least at the beginning) democratic institutions and procedures (like selection of the king), not less significant for the whole socio-political system's operation (see, e.g., Diesner 1966; Claude 1970; Dvoretskaja 1982). Hence, the questions which rise are if in a given social system there is only one hierarchy or there many of them? and in the latter case, are the hierarchies ranked rigidly or not: do, say, two individuals find themselves ranked towards each other the same way in any social context or not?
Every hierarchy in a society is underpinned by a specific set of values. A society may be considered as homoarchic when there is one value which is central to all the hierarchies and not only integrates but also arranges in a definite pyramidal order all the other, secondary to it, values and hierarchies they underpin. Under such circumstances this value 'encompasses' all the rest and makes the society 'holistic' (Dumont 1966/1980), that is homoarchic when the whole unequivocally dominates parts as the supreme expression of that all-embracing and all-penetrable value. Although Dumont's vision of 'purity' as the value (or idea) encompassing the holistic society in India is criticized nowadays (Mosko 1994b: 24-50; Quigley 1999), his theoretical contribution's validity is nevertheless testified, for example, by the 20th century totalitarian societies in which, e.g. , the idea of communism clearly did play precisely the role Dumont attributes to that of purity in the case of India. On the contrary, when 'there is a multiplicity of "hierarchical" or asymmetrical oppositions, none of which are reducible to any of the others or to a single master opposition or value', 'the ... case immediately departs from the Dumontian formulation' (Mosko 1994a: 214) - the society does not fit the homoarchic (or hierarchic in the Dumontian sense) model.
So, I hope that the idea of homoarchy may serve as a useful counterpart for that of heterarchy (Bondarenko and Crumley 2004; see also Barry, III 2004; Cook 2004; Reicher 2004).
Besides, also very importantly, I believe it is legitimate to apply notions, heterarchy and homoarchy, not to power relations only (to what Crumley destines the former of them1) but within a broader framework of social relations and structure in general. In his review of one of Crumley's recent articles on heterarchy Robert Carneiro asks: 'But by introducing this term into the study of political evolution does Crumley really enhance our understanding of the process?' (2004: 163). The answer the patriarch of cultural evolutionist studies gives himself is strongly in the negative. I would dare disagree with Carneiro and say that in my opinion, the concept of heterarchy is a significant contribution to anthropological theory (to what its growing popularity testifies [see, e.g., Ehrenreich et al. 1995; Haggis et al. 2003; Scarborough et al. 2003; Alexeev et al. 2004: 5-17]) even in its present (initial) form. In the meantime I hope that its broadening first, by supplementing with the notion of homoarchy and second, by extending its inclusion up to the whole scope and variety of relations in society, could make the concept's validity even higher.
Fair dissatisfaction with the 'classical' unilineal typological schemes like 'from band to state' (Service 1962/1971) or 'from egalitarian organization to state society' (Fried 1967) growing especially rapidly from the second half of the 1980s (see particularly, Mann 1986; Maisels 1987; Upham 1990; Yoffee 1993; Ehrenreich et al. 1995; McIntosh 1999; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a; Claessen 2000; Kradin et al. 2000; Guidi 2002; Grinin et al. 2004), has resulted in thus much fair and theoretically prospective shift of researchers' emphasis from societies as isolated entities to them as elements of wider cultural networks, and in connection with it, from evolutionary stages to transformation processes. However, I do believe that Carneiro (2000; 2003: 155-156) is essentially right when he argues that the dichotomy 'process versus stages' is 'false': both are important. (In the meantime, I leave apart the problems I feel with Carneiro's concrete interpretation concentrated in such 'minor linguistic peculiarities' as that I would prefer to
speak in the multilinear vein about 'processes', not 'the process' and about 'types' besides 'stages'). The problem is not that there are as if no social types or that in fact there are much more of them than four, but that they cannot be arranged on the 'stairs' of one 'ladder', and that purely typological thinking, especially in the unilineal style prevents from giving full consideration to those changes which crucially transform a society but do not pull it to the next stair of the notorious types ladder.
In particular, the groundbreaking in my opinion 'dual-pro-cessual theory' elaborated in the last decade by Mesoamericanists (e.g., Blanton 1994; Feinman 1995; Blanton et al. 1996), is aimed at the same idea as the heterarchy - homoarchy: '... to account for variation among societies of similar complexity and scale' (Blanton et al. 1996: 1). Note that the dichotomy of homoarchic and heterarchic societies is observable at all the levels of social complexity (see Bondarenko 1997b: 10-15; 1998a, 1998c, 2000c; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000c; Bondarenko et al. 2002; Koro-tayev et al. 2000) and furthermore, in the course of history a society can change its internal organization from homoarchic to heter-archic or vice versa, not infrequently without a change of its overall level of complexity (for some of many examples of the latter case, see Leach 1954; Shkunayev 1988; Levy 1995; Korotayev 1996; Kowalewski 2000). Though it would be completely wrong to argue that, for instance, 'the network strategy' leads to heterarchy while 'the corporate strategy' gives rise to (generally) homoarchic societies or vice versa, I feel that the two approaches may be complementary within the general explanatory framework seeking to propose 'a suitable behavioral theory' (Blanton et al. 1996: 1) of the socio-cultural types variability, particularly as both of them concentrate on the dialectics of the individual and the group, and centralization and decentralization, and attempt '... to move beyond a typology approach.' (White 1995: 119; emphasis in the original). However, I agree with one of the dual-processual theory advocates, Paul Wason (e.g., Wason and Baldia 2000) that 'with due caution, a typological approach is still valid.' (Wason 1995: 25). Establishing such a link, being beyond the present generally typological article's purposes, is a task for the future2.
INTRODUCTION: WHAT IS CALLED THE STATE?
The overwhelming majority of modern theories of the state consider this phenomenon as a specialized and centralized institution for governing a society, to what its right to exercise coercive authority - legitimized violence is often added as the state's critical characteristic feature (see e.g., 'summarizing' definitions in anthropological encyclopedias, text-books, and general publications of the last decade: Earle 1994: 945; Claessen 1996; Marcus and Feinman 1998: 4; Ember and Ember 1999: 226-229, 242; Abeles 2000; Kradin 2004: 268). This approach to the state, rooted in political, philosophic, legal, and anthropological thought from Antiquity on (Hodgen 1964: 354-515; Harris 1968; Service 1975: 21-46; 1978; Nersesjants 1985; 1986; Iljushechkin 1996: 13-92; Gomerov 2002: 14-68), in the 20th century became equally typical of Marxists, (neo)evolutionists, and structuralists notwithstanding all the differences between them3. We may argue safely that these two characteristics - political centralization ('the "concentration" of power in the hands of a few' [Roscoe 1993: 113]) and specialization of administration, form the backbone of the theory of the state in general4.
However, contrary to the postulate of political anthropology's Founding Fathers, Fortes and Evans-Pritchard (1940/1987: 5), political centralization cannot be regarded as a specifically state's feature as it is applicable more or less to all forms of complex ho-moarchic (organized 'vertically') societies including chiefdoms first and foremost5. Even more so, in current research of the statelevel polities '... there is a clear movement away from a view of states as highly centralized, omnipotent entities toward a heterogeneous model that recognizes variability in state/urban organization and explores the limits of state power within the broader society' (Stein 1998: 10). Good examples of such movement have recently been provided by Blanton (1998) and Kristiansen (1998). However, it must be noted that e.g., when Kristiansen postulates the opposition between 'the decentralized archaic state' and 'the centralized archaic state ' (1998: 46-48)6, he de facto means that the former is less centralized than the latter but not that it is not centralized at all. Is it really true lack of centralization (if it is not mixed up with one person's omnipotence or lack of intermediary
administrative levels) when 'government is carried out (by "the warrior chiefs and king" - D. B.) through regional and local vassal chiefs.' (1998: 46)?!7 It would be better to describe such a society as politically centralized but disintegrated (and what Kristian-sen calls the centralized archaic state as politically [more] centralized integrated one).
In the meantime, specialization resulting in professionalization is precisely the feature which is typical of the state only, it is not by chance that in the specialization of the administrative apparatus scholars usually see the brink between the state and all the nonstate forms of socio-political organization, again including homo-archic ones like the chiefdom and complex chiefdom (see Wright 1977: 381-385; Earle 1978: 1-7; Godiner 1991; Belkov 1995: 171-175; Spencer 1998; Blanton et al. 1999: 112; Johnson and Earle 2000: 245-329; Bondarenko 2001: 244-245). So, I shall agree with Charles Spencer's (1998: 5) elegantly simple dictum (the first part of which I have already just quoted in note 5 and which is based on Henry Wright's seminal publication of 1977): specifically chiefdoms are 'societies with centralized but not internally specialized authority', and states are 'societies with centralized and also internally specialized authority' (see also Earle 1987: 289). 'A state administration, from this perspective, is inherently bureaucratic' (Spencer 2003: 11185; see also Cohen 1978).
Indeed, what makes the administrative apparatus specialized? It becomes such when it is 'filled' with professional (i.e., permanent and full-time) administrators thus forming bureaucracy. Max Weber elaborated the most authoritative concept of bureaucracy and his ideas form an implicit or explicit background for most of influential modern theories of the state8. Though not all the famous Weber's ten features of bureaucracy could apply to preindustrial states mainly because his definition is based on executive and decision-making functions only (Morony 1987: 9-10), and although it is stressed sometimes (recently, e.g., by Claessen and Oosten [1996: 5-6; Claessen 2003: 162], Kristiansen [1998: 45, 46], Johnson and Earle [2000: 248], Chabal, Feinman, and Skalnik [2004: 28], Christian [2004: 273-274], and Kradin [2004: 179]) that bureaucracy can be poorly developed in early states, it must be admitted that it still has to be present as such if a given society is attributed as a state. In the meantime, even most complex among all complex
chiefdoms, like Cahokia (Pauketat 1994; Milner 1998), the Powhatan paramountcy (Potter 1993; Rountree and Turner III 1998), or Hawaii (Earle 1978, 1997, 2000) notwithstanding their political sophistication, could not boast of having professional administrators at all. The existence of specialized administration was also improbable in Benin of the First (Ogisos) dynasty time, in the 10th - 12th centuries (see Bondarenko 2001: 108-117) attributed by me as a complex chiefdom elsewhere (Bondarenko 2000b: 102-103; 2001: 133-135; 2004: 340).
WAS THERE BENIN BUREAUCRACY?
So, it looks reasonable to examine the list of the bureaucrats' characteristic features Weber singled out. Do they fit titled chiefs -administrators of the 13 th - 19th centuries Benin Kingdom?9 (For a more detailed analysis see Bondarenko 2001: 212-250; 2002). Weber (1922/1947: 333-334) wrote about bureaucrats:
(1) They are personally free and subject to authority only with respect to their impersonal official obligations;
(2) They are organized in a clearly defined hierarchy of offices; (3) Each office has a clearly defined sphere of competence in the legal sense; (4) The office is filled by a free contractual relationship. Thus, in principle, there is free selection; (5) Candidates... are appointed, not elected; (6) They are remunerated by fixed salaries. ; (7) The office is treated as a sole, or at least the primary, occupation of the incumbent; (8) It constitutes a career... ; (9) The official works entirely separated from ownership of the means of administration and without appropriation of his position; (10) He is subject to strict and systematic discipline and control in the conduct of the office.
Are there any grounds to regard Benin titled chiefs as bureaucrats i.e., professional administrators?10
Every Benin chief belonged to one of the two broad categories: his title was either hereditary (what is impossible if he is really a bureaucrat - see Weber's point 9) or not. There were quite few hereditary titles in the Benin Kingdom: those of the most aristocratic title-holders congregation members - the Uzama NIhinron (the 'kingmakers'), ranked highest among all the chiefs (initially there were six and from the middle of the 15th century seven of them),
and of several other, less important dignitaries. The Uzama Nlhin-ron was established in the 13th century by the first ruler of the Second Dynasty - Eweka I and the majority of other hereditary titles appeared in the time of Oba (supreme ruler) Ewuare in the mid-15th century.
Non-hereditary title-holders were considered as 'appointed by the Oba' and fell into two major groups, besides some other, secondary by their significance in the administrative mechanism. The first of those two categories was called Eghaevbo N'Ogbe (the 'palace chiefs'). This institution was established by the fourth supreme ruler, Ewedo within the framework of his anti-Uzama actions in the mid-13th century. The Eghaevbo N'Ogbe were divided into three 'palace societies'. Each of these societies, in its turn, also fell into three groups imitating the Bini's traditional age-sets system. The kingmakers were really pushed to the background but eventually those were not the Obas but the palace chiefs who came to the fore. The significance of the Eghaevbo N'Ogbe was great. This association members received their might due not only to their official titles and rights but also, maybe even first of all owing to their proximity to the supreme ruler. One of their main tasks was to serve mediators between the Oba and the people, for the prohibition to communicate with his subjects freely seems to be among the supreme ruler's taboos already at least in the beginning of the 17th century. Hence, the palace chiefs could rather easily 'regulate' the information flows to and from the palace in their own interests. From the European written sources of the 17th - 19th centuries one can see that these chiefs really did it, and also see, what a considerable might the Eghaevbo NOgbe under the leadership of Uwangue concentrated in their hands that time. Eventually, in the 17th century the palace chiefs, and not the supreme ruler's lineage or the Uzama members furthermore, played the decisive role in the selection of the descendent to the throne.
Another major category of non-hereditary title-holders, the Eghaevbo NOre (the 'town chiefs') was established later, in the mid-15th century by Ewuare, already as a counterbalance to the palace chiefs though basically they were ranked lower than the Eghaevbo NOgbe. They struggled actively with the latter for the influence on the Obas and also fought for power with the supreme
rulers themselves. All in all, the town chiefs were a success. The Eghaevbo NOre's struggle for power was led by the head of this category of title-holders, the lyase (whose own title was introduced much earlier, in the mid-13th century by Oba Ewedo). In the course of time, he became the most powerful and influential figure in the Benin administrative system and society. Since the Eghaevbo NOre's introduction the antagonism of the lyases to the Obas, as Kochakova remarks (1986: 244), 'runs all through the whole space of the Benin history'. Even the supplanting of the British colonial administration could not cease their rivalry.
So, the Eghaevbo NOgbe and Eghaevbo NOre, whose behavior was very far from that 'ordered' to them by Weber (in point 10) were the principal associations of non-hereditary chiefs in the Benin Kingdom. However, the Obas appointed chiefs just formally, for firstly, to be distinct, the supreme ruler appointed only the lineage out of which its members (officially not involved into the administrative system) selected a concrete person for granting the title. Second, due to the strength of the tradition and real might of the palace and town chiefs, titles were held within the same extended families (egbes) for hundreds of years (though officially every lawful Bini man could claim for a non-hereditary title).
Thus in reality there was no free choice of administrators and their appointment by higher authorities. In practice, administrators were not appointed at all as well as there was no free selection of them on the societal level; they were elected within definite lineages and extended families. Only their more or less formal investiture was the Oba's privilege and duty (compare with Weber's points 5 and 4). The sovereign's power over distant chiefdoms' rulers could be rather weak (Bradbury 1957: 33; 1973: 178) and it may be reasonable to suppose (especially if one trusts the folklore evidence [Sidahome 1964: 49-50, 163]) that during the last turbulent centuries of the Benin Kingdom's existence the Obas only blindly confirmed the candidatures proposed to him and this procedure in its essence transformed into a mere pro forma, the performing of an ancient ritual ('anti-point 9' of Weber).
The chiefs were not simple officials at the supreme ruler's service. On the one hand, the Obas regularly established ties of
relationship with them (what contradicts Weber's point 1) marrying the titled chiefs' daughters and giving their own daughters in marriage to the chiefs. On the other hand, the chiefs constantly preserved close connections with the kinship organization and fulfilled different non-administrative functions ascribed to them as kin units members (hence, the Benin realities did not fit point 7 of Weber). In the central bodies' activities they also participated as representatives of their titled lineages, not as individuals. Titled chiefs exercised control over communities through local leaders. It was unreal to dig titled chiefs up from their native social units and to send them to govern 'alien' communities (iyas)n. Under the conditions when all the levels of socio-political complexity were penetrated by communal in their essence ties and relations which dominated at all of them, the division of the country into merely administrative units (including by means of transforming into administrative units communities and chiefdoms) was impossible.
The supreme chiefs always were first and foremost not post-but title-holders. A chief could be deprived from his post by the Oba's command, but the title, once given rested with the chief till the end of his life. The native historian, ethnographer, and courtier Jacob Egharevba openly argued (1949: 24) that the supreme ruler '... could, suspend any titled chief from his post, but the chief must still hold his title for life' (see also Egharevba 1956: 6; Igbafe 1979: 4). The chiefs received all their privileges in accordance with titles and were not rewarded just for posts they held. The post was an unavoidable enclosure to the title. For example, in reality the post could demand from the 'Oba's wardrobe keeper' not cleaning and airing of his robes at all, but attending to certain duties by no means connected with such a kind of activities. These duties were not clearly defined and separated from those of other chiefs as well as all the categories of titled chiefs comprised officials of all kinds - priests, war leaders, etc. (compare with what Weber wrote in point 3).
Henri Claessen and Peter Skalník (1978: 576) distinguish two major types of functionaries in early states: '(a) general functionaries, whose activities embrace a number of types of governmental function; (b) special functionaries, whose governmental activities are restricted to only one aspect of government administration'.
Their sample's analysis allowed to formulate the regularities as follows: 'In early states general functionaries are found mostly on the regional level.' and 'In early states specialist functionaries are usually found at the top level of the administrative apparatus' (Claessen and Skalnik 1978: 579, 580). Basing on the aforesaid we can argue without hesitation that in Benin general functionaries the top administrative level was dominated by general functionaries absolutely. There was a dim notion of higher and lower titles and more or less important duties among the Bini and for some functionaries these or those of their numerous and diverse duties were regarded as principal or primary. For example, in the Uzama NI-hinron the Ezomo title holders' main role was that of a general, and Eholo NIre's cardinal task was priestly. However, even many other members of this most aristocratic chiefs grade had no one dominant function besides the function which was common for all the Uzama members: in earlier times to select and later only to inaugurate every new Oba. There was no fixed hierarchy neither within the supreme chiefs' congregations (most often, only their heads were definitely known) nor within these or those spheres of activities -administrative, priestly and so on (compare with point 2 of Weber).
The material well-being of the supreme chiefs (at least prior to the period of active trade with Europeans [Ryder 1969; Bon-darenko 1995a: 153-157]) was based on receiving of a share of what had been produced in their communities. It was not dependent crucially either on their share in tribute once or twice a year collected by them for the Oba or on the sovereign's 'presents' chiefs used to get from time to time. In fact, those undefined share in tribute and occasional monarch's gifts stood for fixed salaries which have never been due to them at all (nothing in common with Weber's point 6).
As titles belonged to the same lineages for centuries, there was no free competition for titles in the society. Then, there were no opportunities for making a career, for chiefs held first and foremost titles, and titles besides lack of their well-defined hierarchy, were not subjected to their changing by a person. Having once got a title, he could not only lose it by the Oba's command but also receive another one, in addition to, or exchange for the previous one (compare to Weber's point 8).
So, our attempt to apply the Weber's features of bureaucracy to the Benin Kingdom of the 13 th - 19th centuries reveals that none of them, including the most significant - independence of the kin organization, was characteristic of her titled chiefs. In fact, even the sovereign did not completely desert the communal organization (Bondarenko 1995a: 203-231; 2001: 193-211). The 'communal spirit' revealed itself in his support (including economic) by the populace, and his subjects not at all perceived the supreme ruler as a power alien for the community. 'He who owns you / Is among you here' are the lines of a medieval verse devoted to a new Oba's inthronization (Elimimian 1986: 105). Just the fact that the Oba's power was considered as continuation and strengthening of the legitimate community heads' authority at a new level, guaranteed the continuity of fundamental features of political organization at a change of rulers on the throne or of the general apportionment of forces in the upper strata. In its turn, the community provided the society with socio-economic firmness.
Indeed, though it is evident that the Oba shared many non-bureaucratic features of titled chiefs the analysis will not be complete if some more attention to the sovereign as a supreme administrator is not paid. In the situation when the basic unit in a society was not the individual but the collectivity, and kin relations were the background of the whole system of government up to its highest level (Bradbury 1957: 31), a new Oba came to power as a representative of his kin group first and foremost. The claims of the royal clan (egbe umogun) for supreme power besides 'proofs' by different myths (see Talbot 1926: III, 961-962; Beier 1980: 19-20), were substantiated in the idea of its members' descent from the father of the Second dynasty's founder Oranmiyan - Oduduwa, a deity and the first supreme ruler (Oni) of the sacred Yoruba town of Ife (called Uhe by the Bini). In the meantime, there was also another source of the dynasty's legitimacy: 'As the descendant of a deified Yoruba king, the Oba rules by divine right. Yet he is also an Edo12, ruling with the permission of a council of "kingmaker" chiefs whose authority predates his own' (Gallagher 1983: 21). Both in official ideology and common people's consciousness the two sources of the dynasty's legitimacy were equally important and mutually complementary: 'The tradition indicates that neither of these loci of legitimacy is alone sufficient. Although the dual man-
date was a source of continuing political conflict for the Oba, it was also the ultimate source of his power' (ibid.).
Rather numerous (Bradbury 1957: 27-30) royal clan though privileged, had typical for the Bini extended families structure and mechanisms of functioning what revealed itself especially vividly in the rules of succession and their changes in the course of history (see Bondarenko 1995a: 194-203; 2001: 194-197). Due to this the Oba (typically not the senior in kin at the moment of accession to the throne) if he was a weak ruler, could even 'become the prisoner of his own hierarchic, ambitious household' (Ryder 1969: 6).
However, the Oba was invariably officially recognized as omnipotent and the possessor of all (land, people, etc.) in his realm (e.g., Dapper 1668/1975: 168; 1671: 491; Thomas 1910: I, 91; Ajisafe 1945: 25, 75, 95; Bradbury 1957: 44; Akenzua 1974: 3; Jones 1983: 40). Nevertheless, neither the first nor the second was so in reality (as European visitors clearly understood [Van Nyen-dael 1705: 430; Smith, W. 1744: 228; Gallwey 1893: 129]). Particularly, land was held by communities while slaves were only prisoners of war and criminals (e.g.: Dennett 1910: 199; Ajisafe 1945: 75-76; Egharevba 1949: 65-66, 77; Ogbobine 1974: 17; Nwankwo 1987: 48). The phrases like 'all the land in Benin belongs to the Oba and all her inhabitants are his slaves' reflected attitude to him as to the guarantee of the country and populace's prosperity. This formula also served a means for expressing the idea of all Benin citizens' supracommunal unity symbolized and personalized by the sovereign.
As for the Oba's essence as a political figure and his true role in government (with what I am concerned now), power was divided between him on the one hand, and titled chiefs of all the categories on the other. The supreme ruler was always considered as a member of all the ruling bodies (Dapper 1668/1975: 167-169; Talbot 1926: III, 581-590; Egharevba 1949: 29-33; 1960: 78-82; Bradbury 1957: 35-39) including the titled chiefs council participated by members of twenty-one grade of administrators (Ajisafe 1945: 18; Egharevba 1949: 29; 1960: 78-80; Bradbury 1957: 43-44; Igbafe 1979: 10-11). Notwithstanding this, the distribution of power between the sovereign and the chiefs was historically dynamic and had dialectics of its own. The 'profane functions - sacral duties' dichotomy was crucial at this point.
The institution of the Oba appeared as a combination of profane functions and sacral duties in one person, and the struggle between the Oba and the chiefs took the form of constant and gradually successful attempts of the latter to limit the sovereign's profane power by means of inflicting new binding taboos on him13 and hence volens nolens increasing his sacrality inversely proportional for 'lists' of royal taboos (see, e.g., Adams 1823: 111-113; Talbot 1926: III, 736-737). The final act ran high in the early 17th century when the chiefs succeeded in depriving the Oba of the right to command the army in person (Egharevba 1960: 32-33, 34; for the whole story see Bondarenko 2000e). Relations of the Europeans who visited the Benin court in the late 16th - 19th centuries are full of vivid stories and surprised or contemptuous remarks testifying to the 'king''s complete impotence at the face of his 'noblemen' and relatives (Ingram 1588/1904: 298; Van Nyendael 1705: 449; Gallwey 1892/1969: 345, 346; 1893: 129; Bindloss 1898/1968: 205; Boisragon 1898: 165; Leonard 1906: 372; Egharevba 1952: 14)14.
This became possible due to the specifics of the Bini's consciousness in general and political consciousness in particular. In their minds, the true ruler is not the one who holds real (in our rational modern view) control levers but the one who is endowed with sacral power. Actually, Obas themselves did a lot to increase the level of their sacralization, especially Oba Ewuare of the mid-15th century. By no means did the Oba become powerless: in the Benin society and culture context, sacral power was a specific kind of real power which allowed to limit effectively behavioral alternatives of the subjects (Bondarenko 1995a: 227-230). By the very fact of his presence on the throne the Oba went on playing the exceptionally important and 'practical' role of the all-Benin unity's symbol and thus did promote significantly the integration of sociopolitical segments into a whole - centralization in its socio-territorial aspect15. Characteristically, as a 'barbarian', 'foreigner' (ete") in Benin there was considered not any ethnically non-Bini but only the one 'who does not know the law (of the country - D. B.) and does not recognize the Oba' (Melzian 1937: 43). This critical role of the Oba became especially clear in the colonial times when after an attempt to abolish the institution immediately after the fall of Benin in 1897, the British had to restore it in 1914 as
far as it had become evident that 'if they were to secure even the grudging co-operation of the Bini they must restore the monarchy' (Igbafe 1975: 175; see also Zotova 1979: 105-114; Neva-domsky 1993: 66-67).
In general relations between the rulers (all-Benin authorities) and the ruled (communalists) were those of mutual necessity and complementary. Sargent (1986) has defined the relations between the supreme authorities and the community as exploitative (and called the former 'bureaucracy') but in reality in Benin there were no conditions for such relations' appearance (Bondarenko 1995a: 257-264, 273-274; for the criticism at Sargent's inadequate attempt to use Marxist categories in the analysis of Benin, see: Manning 1986; Wilks 1986). Power was not separated from the people in the Morgan - Engels's sense (Bradbury 1969: 21; Bondarenko 1993a: 165) what above all signifies that the all-Benin institutions' formation, recruitment of administrators into them, and the exercise of power by them took place in accordance with the community-kinship traditions, by means of the mechanisms determined by them. Not only heads of communities and chiefdoms through which titled chiefs coordinated relations between the Kingdom's parts and the whole, but also titled chiefs themselves did not become bureaucrats. They remained chiefs with all the mechanisms of coming to, and exercising of power, rights, privileges, duties, etc. typical of them.
There were also provided massive ideological pillars for this objective situation (see Bondarenko 2000a, 2000e; 2001: 186-188). At this point it is significant to note that it would be unreasonable to speak about the imposition of ideology 'from above' or self-deceiving of those at the social bottom: at least until the start of active trade with Europeans in the late 15 th century Benin was characterized by mental continuity - principal identity of all the social groups' Weltanschauung (Bondarenko 1995a: 90-91, 165, 254-255) which also witnesses to the lack of unbridgeable gulf between the rulers and the ruled. People felt their complicity to power, its institutions and holders. As a result, 'a passion for legality and order' as a typical feature of African kingdoms (Armstrong 1960: 38) characterized Benin among others. Owe to this, Benin history of the Obas period did not see revolts of the masses against central power except the uprisings in subjugated lands (and possi-
bly just one episode in Benin City in the 14th or 15th century [see Bondarenko 2001: 176-177]).
Such a trend of the Bini political culture kept easily within the framework of their general mental and behavioral paradigm. Every Bini was responsible for the realization of the Bini's 'national idea': an indefatigable vigil about permanent reestablishment of status quo in all spheres including political; first of all, by supporting proper relations between the living and the ancestors for the sake of subsequent existence of Benin and the whole universe (see Bondarenko 1995a: 73-89, 258-261; 1997a: 111, 119-122). In this respect, really in Benin 'everyone is the priest for himself '16 (Van Nyendael 1705: 448). However, the unit leaders from the extended family level up to the 'national' one bore higher responsibility than commoners did, as their deeds unavoidably were not individual acts but those in their units' name. The widest, all-embracing unit (and actually cult group) was Benin society as a whole. The Oba, perceived as the father of all the Bini, was the supreme mediator in the alive - ancestors' relations. Performing rites of the group ancestors' cult (erha) was regarded as the most important of the leader's tasks. Hence, those valuable people caring of bien public deserved just gratitude and help, not preventing from fulfilling their duty. Encroachment on the authority (ase) was thus incredible (see Bondarenko 1994: 6-9; 1995a: 182, 260, 276-277).
For the Bini, universe was divided into mutually penetrable domains of people on the one hand, and ancestors' spirits and deities on the other. But this was one world fastened by power, its institutions and holders; each on the respective level. In fact, for the Bini, they existed precisely for the sake of integrating the universe (see Bondarenko 1995a: 24-89, 182-183; 1997a; 2000a: 192). This is why power, both the substance and its implementation in political institutions including that of the supreme ruler first and foremost, was surrounded with a halo of sacrality. Rooted and actively exercised in the community but also elevated to the rank of allBenin ideology, the essentially kin ancestor worship could be only a thin pillar for the rise of bureaucracy. In this respect, an instructive example is provided by ancient China. Bureaucracy did not form there until ancestor worship was overshadowed by other religious cults and practices (rituals associated with the 'Mandate of Heaven' and some others) in the Warring States era of the 5th - 3rd centuries B.C. (Baum 2004).
Resuming the analysis provided in the present section, I feel quite safe to argue that Benin was politically centralized but her administrative system was not specialized. Contrary to the First (Ogisos) dynasty, the Second dynasty rulers of the 13th - 19th centuries turned out capable to establish true supremacy of the central political institutions over the society i.e., to make effective their domination over it. But in essentially communal Benin society even those who governed it on the top level were not professional administrators - 'bureaucrats'. Thus, in accordance with the practically generally accepted idea of intimate connection between the state and bureaucracy, Benin cannot and should not be considered as a state.
WAS BENIN A SUPRA-KIN-BASED SOCIETY?
In the meantime, by the 13th century Benin had historically passed and culturally no doubt superceded the complex chiefdom at the level of which it was in the 10th - 12th centuries though such traits of the preceding period as e.g., ethnic heterogeneity and non-participation of the supra-simple-chiefdom elite in subsistence production were inherited and strengthened further (see Bondarenko 2000b: 106-112; 2001: 232-243; 2004: 344-348). At the same number of complexity levels (two above local community) and socio-economic background (extended-family-based community and slash-and-burn hoe agriculture), Benin of the Obas demonstrated an incomparably higher degree of integration, unity, and centralization. In her social complexity level, economic parameters, governmental apparatus' hierarchicity, and the spiritual sphere the Benin Kingdom was an equivalent of early states. Nevertheless, the society was still based on the homoarchic 'matrix' of the Bini community which consisted of extended families.
The community was characterized by a tangle of kin and neighbor ties dominated by kinship and by explicit social and administrative homoarchicity expressed particularly in unreserved superiority of the seniors over the juniors in any social interaction both in the family and (as an outcome of this [Sidahome 1964: 128)] the community (Egharevba 1949: 67-70; Bradbury 1957: 23-25; 1973: 149-209; Roese and Rees 1994: 543-545; Bondarenko 2001: 39-55). The age-grade system - otu (see Thomas
1910: I, 11-12; Talbot 1926: III, 547-549; Bradbury 1957: 15, 32, 34, 49-50; 1973: 170-175; Igbafe 1979: 13-15), was a proper means for permanent reproduction of the homoarchic status quo effectively preventing autocracy in the community (as a group of persons - senior age-grade members had the right and duty to participate in its government) at one time. The principle of gerontocracy dominated in administration at the community and even more so extended family levels (Bradbury 1969; Sargent 1986; Kochakova 1991). The seniors' power rested upon the idea of their maximal proximity to the group's ancestors who were thought of as true collective landowners (Talbot 1926: II, 37-38, 308; III, 737; Nwankwo 1987: 47, 50) and on whose will people's well-being was believed to depend crucially.
By mentioning the communal matrix, the kin character of central for the society religious beliefs (and at the same time ideology), etc. we come to one more aspect of the problem of the state which is more or less consciously evicted from many contemporary definitions due to the wide-spread approach to the state as merely a specific set of political institutions17 (as well as to cultures in comparison with which the state is defined; e.g., Earle [1991: 14] postulates unequivocally that '... chiefdoms must be understood as political systems'). This aspect, intrinsically interdependent with the problem of bureaucracy, is coming to the fore of the non-kin, territorial relations in the society. Although at dawn of the 20th century Schurtz (1902) and ultimately British structuralists and American Boasians demonstrated in their fieldwork-based researches as far back as in the middle of the last century that Morgan (as well as Maine [1861; 1880] before and Engels [1884/1985]18 after him) had postulated the opposition between kinship and territoriality too rigidly (Evans-Pritchard 1940: 198 ff.; Fortes and Evans-Pritchard 1940/1987: XIV-XX, 6-7, 10-11; Lowie 1948: 10-12, 317-318; Schapera 1956; Middleton and Tait 1958: 5; Mair 1965: 99-100)19, I believe that the criterion as such still deserves attention. I consider it reasonable to distinguish the state in two respects: as a system of political institutions and as a type of society to which this political form becomes adequate. The latter normally is a broader notion, for on the one hand, it supplements political characteristics by and combines them with social (and through them economic) ones while on the other hand, most
frequently20 the political system of the state kind ripens out earlier than the respective social system based on the territorial division of the citizens and composition of the polity21. If we attempt at characterizing a society (or 'culture' in the American cultural anthropologists' thesaurus) as a whole, we must recognize the political system as only one of its subsystems and hence label the society/culture according to its more general feature - the societal type, and this should be so not with respect to the state only but with regards to any society (see Bondarenko 1989, 1991, 1993b, 1996a; 2001: 244-250)22.
I shall not argue either, following Maine (1861, 1880), Morgan (1877), and Engels (1884/1985), that the state in full sense begins when division by territory supplants that by kin practically completely, or in accordance with Claessen and Skalnik, that the 'inchoate' but nevertheless state may be '... associated with dominant kinship, family and community ties in the field of politics.' (1978: 589) but will rather take an intermediate position. Bearing in mind the older idea that in the state 'territory' dominates over 'kinship' on the one hand, and taking into account the mentioned above achievements of the 20th century anthropologists and historians, I shall say that the state in its full sense may be fixed in the situation when territorial ties clearly (though not absolutely) dominate over those of kinship on the supra-local levels of society's complexity. This threshold is lower than that established particularly by Morgan but higher than the one sufficient for Claessen and (until a certain moment) Skalnik23. In fact, in my view, 'the completed state' corresponds only to 'the transitional early state' in the latter scholars' scheme '. in which the administrative apparatus was dominated by appointed officials, where kinship affected only certain marginal aspects of government.' (ibid.)24. As for the state in the narrower - merely political sense, 'the limited state', I would regard as such the societies which have reached at least the level of 'the typical early state' of Claessen and Skalnik (ibid.) - '. the kind of state in which ties of kinship were [still only] counterbalanced by those of locality, ... [but] where non-kin officials and title-holders [already] played the leading role in government admini-stration.'25 Note, that even highly developed pre-state cultures, like complex chiefdoms are normally characterized as essentially kin-based societies (see Earle 1997: 5).
In the meantime, what I see as a true and verifiable criterion of territorial (i.e., the state in its broader, full sense) organization is the possibility for rulers to recarve arbitrarily traditional, determined by kin grouping, division of the country's territory into parts. Provided it is possible (for instance, if the central authority can unite them with others or cut into parts), one can argue that even if those social entities preserved their initial internal form, they were nothing more than administrative (and taxpaying) units in the wider context of the whole state polity administered by functionaries either appointed or confirmed outside the community - in the political center. Characteristically in states commu-nalists are not only imposed different obligations but also given the right to sell communal land, what would undoubtedly undermine the society's background if it had really been community-based. The 3rd - 2nd millennia B.C. Near East gives especially vivid examples of the aforesaid (besides many publications on particular societies, see in general and comparative works, e.g., Childe 1942: 122-123; Butinov 1967; Zak 1975: 242-265; Maisels 1987: 345-346; Iljushechkin 1990: 160-162; Jakobson 1997: 51, 60, 102, 105, 107; Diakonoff and Jakobson 1998; Baines and Yoffee 1998: 225-227; Kuzishchin 1999: 5-7). Generally speaking, in a state the supreme power does not develop the community matrix further on but rather 'on the contrary begins to restructure society' in its own image (Beliaev 2000: 194) what results in 'the encompassment of the local sphere by the state' (Tanabe 1996: 154).
Nothing of the kind can be traced in Benin. The transition from complex chiefdom to the polity of a new sort with the Second dynasty's consolidation led to significant strengthening of centripetal tendencies but nevertheless did not result in socio-political homog-enization. Benin remained a 'multipolity', that is a polity within which structural elements of different socio-political types and complexity levels co-existed and interacted (see Korotayev 2000: 195). Undoubtedly, this situation's lasting for all the many centuries of the Obas Benin history testifies to the fact that such polystratumness was the society's essential feature and not a manifestation of its as if 'transitional character'.
In the previous period chiefdoms and autonomous communi-ties26 co-existed within the complex chiefdom (though strictly
speaking, the theory presupposes that a complex chiefdom consists of simple chiefdoms only, the historical realities of Benin do not contradict but specifies it). In the time of the Obas the same components - chiefdoms and autonomous communities (as before, equal to each other in terms of rights and obligations towards the supreme authorities of the time) formed parts of society of another type. Communities (including autonomous) and chiefdoms preserved all the initial characteristics of their internal organization and went on obeying the all-Benin authorities. The more powerful all-Benin political institutions were becoming the more effective their control over the relations between chiefdoms and communities was (Bradbury 1973: 149, 171). Nonetheless, the all-Benin authority did not intervene in the communities and chiefdoms' internal affairs and reminded of itself only when the interests of the whole country (associated with those of the political center) were infringed, like in the cases of dependencies' attempts to break away in the 'imperial' period of Benin history (mid-15th -19th centuries). What is especially noteworthy is that in no case those units internal composition could be changed (Bondarenko 1995a: 183-193; 2001: 257-264).
Thus, the political center had substantially limited possibilities for exercising coercive authority because violence on its side could not be considered as legitimate if it were aimed directly at the society's component units. In the meantime, the Oba was recognized as not merely the supreme judge but also the only legitimate lawgiver, as it was supposed that only he could relate the ancestors' will without even slight corruption (Ajisafe 1945: 17; Egharevba 1949: 11, 24; 1960: 11, 81; Eweka, E. B. 1989: 34). However, though for the Bini the ancestors were the ultimate source of laws, in reality the regulations were rooted in communal norms and traditions. Due to this new laws met no insurmountable barriers in their path from the Oba's palace to communalists' houses.
In the period under consideration the country consisted not only of chiefdoms and autonomous local communities as before but also of units of a new type. This was a group of communities under the leadership of a paramount chief, like chiefdoms, but the genesis of that socio-political unit was completely different. Such units started to appear from the reign of the first Oba in the result of the supreme ruler's grants of communities to all-Benin chiefs and
royal relatives (Egharevba 1956: 31; Bradbury 1957: 33; 1973: 177). While chiefdom heads were more powerful the farther from the capital their estates were due to their personal enterprise, the Oba himself granted 'pseudochiefdom' heads more prerogatives the more distant from Benin City the territory lay (Bradbury 1973: 150; Imoagene 1990: 28). The pseudochiefdom heads were to compensate the central power's insufficient strength in the country's outskirts. Such units' number especially increased in the time of Benin's active expansion (mid-15th - early 17th centuries).
Characteristically, the Obas could grant titled chiefs only those communities that did not form parts of traditional Bini chiefdoms. Those chiefs actually never resettled there and remained members of their native lineages and communities. The Obas could not subdivide a chiefdom or grant it as a whole to a titled chief. Thus, the pseudochiefdoms of titled chiefs could be compiled exclusively of neighboring autonomous communities. The titled chief who was posed above them carried out in respect to those communities and their members all the same functions as the head of a chiefdom though these responsibilities were secondary for them compared to the duties inflicted on them by high all-Benin titles. Their obligations to the supreme authority were also just the same: collecting tribute, attracting communalists to corvée labor, recruiting of soldiers, etc. Pseudochiefdoms, chiefdoms, and autonomous communities heads - all were subordinated directly to the Oba and were regarded as equals in this respect (Egharevba 1949: 79; Bradbury 1973: 177). The Obas could not subdivide or change the self-administrative system of a community or chiefdom. No chiefdom and only an autonomous community as a whole (not a part of it) could be granted to a titled chief (see Bondarenko 1994: 6-7; 1995a: 183-186, 189-190; 1995c: 140-142, 144-145, 147-150; 2001: 191-193).
So, none of the territorial units the Benin Kingdom comprised can be called administrative in the proper sense. The community and not the central authority remained the true focus of the society throughout the whole Benin history (Bondarenko 1995a, 2001).
Charles Maisels (1987, 1990) emphasized that in what he calls 'city-states', opposite to territorial 'village-states' (see also Trigger 1993), not broad descent groups (such as sibs/clans) but lineage-based extended families (households)27 were the basic
mode of social organization. Though a city-state both as a concept and term seems to me unacceptable at least with respect to Benin (Bondarenko 1995a: 95), the latter definitely was a society of the very type Maisels and Trigger designated that way28. However, there is a significant difference between two subtypes of cultures falling under this category. The first of them is represented by the societies in which typical household and community were based on nuclear families (e.g., Greekpoleis) while the second subtype, and Benin is a good example at this point, is formed by those early urban societies in which community comprised households each of which was an extended family with lineages (not sibs/clans) as their cores29. Particularly, I have shown elsewhere that in Benin not a nuclear but extended family (organized as household integrating a number of patrilineal kindred nuclear families) was the economic and socio-cultural background of the community (Bondarenko 1995a: 136-139; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000b: 174-176). Indeed, what unites both of the subtypes is that their core social institution is household-based community of this or that type30 but while the nuclear-family-based community is essentially and unavoidably non-kin, the extended-family-based one preserves in itself unilineal descent ties.
A useful division can be established within the extended-family households either: between those integrating monogamous and polygynous kindred nuclear families. In Benin polygyny was a norm (Dapper 1668/1975: 162; Gallwey 1893: 129; Thomas 1910: I, 15; Ajisafe 1945: 40; Mercier 1962: 299-303; Ryder 1969: 313; Ahanmisi 1992; Eweka, I. 1998: 161-162) supported by public morality and recognized as a sign of man's might and wealth (Talbot 1926: III, 429; Mercier 1962: 299; Ogieriakhi 1965; Ahanmisi 1992: 98-100). This fact is significant: theoretical research has revealed that general polygyny is rather a strong predictor of social homoar-chicity at both local and supralocal levels of complexity (Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000b; Korotayev and Bondarenko 2000).
Operating with Mesopotamian evidence only, Maisels argues that kin ties within 'minimal lineage' are secondary to non-kin within the entire household (extended family). However, this is not the whole story. First, it should be underlined that a sib/clan does not form the core economic unit in any society either, as it is delo-calized: for example, married women from patrilineal sibs nor-
mally participate incomparably more actively in economic activities of their husbands', not fathers and brothers' groups. Hence, clan communities reveal an interlacing of kin and territorial ties, too. Then, lineage (a group of unilineal relatives of several generations) as Maisels (1987: 348) recognizes, is the 'core' of the household and, let me stress it one more time, is kin group. Only male relatives become both the lineage and household members by birth while all the rest come to the household by means of establishing some (most often marital) relations with them, and only the lineage male members are eligible for heading the household and nuclear families within it being ranked along age lines, social in their essence. So, every extended family demonstrates a mixture of kin and territorial ties by definition but precisely the former integrate and shape the whole. Again, in order to understand an archaic society, first, we should concentrate on community rather than on its components, and second, we must recognize that the problem we are facing is not of the 'presence or absence' but of the 'more or less' sort.
This more or less criterion is still critically important if we look at the extended-family community formed by a number of households (as far as the community consisting of only one extended family and hence identical to it, as the typical, basic socioeconomic unit is a rare case in the preindustrial world31, incredible specifically in Benin where one-family communities could be observed but very infrequently [Egharevba 1949: 11]). We can draw a line between two variants of extended-family communities. The first is that in which extended families within community do not hold kinship relations with each other (as, for instance, among the Bambara and Songhay of Western Africa [Paque 1954: 53-54; Rouch 1954: 43]). In such a situation territorial ties did predominate over kin at the community level. The second variant is represented by Benin (again, among other cultures including African [e.g., McCulloch et al. 1954: 160; Ksenofontova 1970]) where extended families within community preserved kin ties, and thus the latter dominated in the community as a whole though in the interfamily relations they were intertwined with corporate ties of neighborhood32. The bigger was the community the higher was its role as a whole, compared to that of a family as its constituent part (Bradbury 1957: 31).
As has been noted above, the Bini community was of the homoarchic type as it united kindred extended families organized just this way: with the only significant hierarchy within which senior males unavoidably dominated in any social context. Community was the basic, substantial institution not socio-politically only but culturally and economically as well (Bradbury 1957: 15; 1973: 149). Historically, its formation in the late 1st millennium B.C. - early 1st millennium A.D. turned out the initial step on the way to the Benin Kingdom's appearance (see Bondarenko and Roese 1998; Bondarenko 2001: 25-39). Anthropologically, community served the model, a kind of pattern according to which the supra-communal levels were built up homoarchically too, though the transition to higher levels of socio-political organization was accompanied by significant changes. The complex society's integrity was guaranteed by principally the same various mechanisms as that of the community; ideologically, this part was played by ancestors' cult first and foremost which ascribed legitimacy to political institutions (see Bondarenko 1995a: 176-181). Collectivist, hierarchy-oriented dominant features of communalists' thinking, consciousness, Weltanschauung were adequate to, and critically supportive for, the terms and conditions of life in that society33. Precisely the community was not only the focus of the Benin complex society by which it was 'modeled', but also the core of the whole universe in the Bini's outlook (see Bondarenko 1995a: 24-89; 1997a).
Thus, in Benin not the supra-communal institutions were reshaping the community (what is typical of states) but vice versa: they were becoming similar to it. What follows from all the aforesaid is the community's key role in the determination of the character of the mental-cultural, socio-economic, and governmental subsystems of the society. The explanation for many truly and already pseudo-, quasicommunal traits and features of the 13th - 19th centuries Benin society is contained in the aforesaid, too. As the fundamental, basic institution, the community fastened all the levels of its hierarchical structure from birth till death of the Kingdom. In particular, the position of titled chiefs and the sovereign himself clearly witnesses to the kin communal principles' primary importance for the shaping of political system and institutions.
CONCLUSION: HOW TO CALL BENIN?
It looks like the character of a complex society may be predetermined by the specifics of its local (substratum) institution - the community to a greater extent than by the ways of the local and supra-local levels interaction in the process of which the relations of higher order nevertheless do originate. This is not an absolutely strict regulation at all but my (in collaboration with Andrey Korotayev) quantitative cross-cultural research has nevertheless revealed the following. When a community itself is homoarchic (as in the majority of cases when it consists of extended families), a basically communal complex society can well turn out not less homoarchic than even a pre-industrial state which in principle cannot be built up by a community matrix as no community type permits administering by professionals34. As for Benin, the homoar-chic extended-family-based community is still alive even today being the most adequate social framework for agricultural production in the tropical forest zone (Kochakova 1970: 18-25; Bon-darenko 2000d)35. A heterarchic community-matrix-based complex society with higher probability can appear in the milieu of the small-family (neighbor) communities, also heterarchic in their nature (Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000b; see also Blanton 1995; Bondarenko 1998c; 2000c)36.
In the meantime, the way of the Benin Kingdom's formation was through 'likening' of the supra-communal socio-political institutions to the homoarchic community of extended families. The judicial system (see Dapper 1671: 492; Talbot 1926: III, table 19; Egharevba 1949: 11; 1960: 35; Bradbury 1957: 32-33, 41-42; Si-dahome 1964: 127), the system of imposing and collecting tribute (e.g., Van Nyendael 1705: 452-453; Astley 1746: 103; Bradbury 1957: 42-43; Agbontaen 1995: 122-123), etc. - all corresponded to the homoarchic character of the society. Any interaction with supra-familial authorities a common Bini had to realize through the head of his kin unit. However, the head of a family could apply directly to his community leader only. This leader, in his turn, could apply exclusively to the respective chiefdom's head (if the given community was not autonomous), and only the latter (alongside with the autonomous community leader) had the right to solicit the titled chiefs who could make the case known to the su-
preme ruler. Millar resumes in her juvenile but knowledgeable and qualified book (1997: 48-49):
With the Oba at the top [of social pyramid], everyone in Benin had a rank. To do certain things, you had to have the correct rank. Some ranks led. Some followed. ... Top to bottom, Edo [i.e., Bini] chiefs, men, wives, children, and even slaves were arranged into an enormous system of ranks.
So, to sum up, Benin cannot be considered as a state in terms of either Marxism (see also Kochakova 1986: 9, 11), including 'structural Marxism', or (neo)evolutionism, or structuralism; even the existence of the monarchy does not presuppose the state character of society (Oosten 1996; Quigley 1995; Wilkinson 1999; Si-monse 2002; Skalník 2002)37. The 13th - 19th centuries Benin form of socio-political organization can be defined as 'megacommunity', and its structure can be depicted as four concentric circles which in their totality represent an upset cone: the extended family, community, chiefdom, and megacommunity (kingdom) (for detail see Bondarenko 1994; 1995a: 276-284; 1995b, 1996b, 1998d; 2000b: 106-117; 2001: 230-263; 2004). No doubt, this is not a coincidence but a display of their interdependence that 'objective' socio-political structure was paralleled by 'subjective' Bini's vision of the world. The universe was perceived by the Bini as hierarchically structured entity, also a system of four circles: the human being - terrestrial space - the world of spirits and supreme deities -the world on the whole38. Community was perceived by the Bini as the socio-cultural focus of society and hence the core of the whole world, as for them their society literally was the hub of the universe.
Megacommunal institutions towered above communities and chiefdoms, established their dominance over them but in the essentially communal Benin society with lack of pronounced priority of territorial ties over kin ones, even those who governed at the supreme level could not become professional administrators. The Benin megacommunity's specificity is in organization on rather a vast territory of a complex, 'many-tier' society predominantly on the basis of transformed kin principle supplemented by a 'grain' of territorial one. This basis was inherited from the community, within which extended families preserved kin relations not only
within themselves but with each other as well, supplementing them by relations of neighborhood39.
Indeed, 'extensive socio-political systems can be legitimized in kinship terms.' (Claessen 2000: 150). Even Stalin in the industrialized, territory-based, and heavily bureaucratized Soviet Union was unofficially but routinely used to be called 'father of the peoples' by the propaganda. In Benin political relations were 'naturally' perceived and expressed in kin terms. The spirits of royal ancestors 'spread' their authority on all the Oba's subjects though only the sovereign and his relatives were their descendents. However, in Benin kinship was not only an ideology; it was much more than this - the true, 'objective' socio-cultural background of this supercomplex society.
The megacommunity was a specific type of complex homoar-chic socio-political organization. On the one hand, the Benin megacommunity gives a historical example of positive (nondestructive) transformation of the complex chiefdom. It has repeatedly been argued (by Webb [1975], Peebles and Kus [1977], Wright [1977], Carneiro [1981], Cohen [1981], M. E. Smith [1985], Spencer [1987], Earle [1991], D. Anderson [1994] and others) that a typical fortune of a chiefdom (including complex) is eventual disintegration into its initial components while only some of them turn out to be able to transform into states. The fate of all but one numerous Bini chiefdoms of the mid - late 1st - early 2nd millennia (Obayemi 1976: 242; Darling 1984: I, 119-124, 130-142) confirmed this regularity (see Bondarenko 1999: 27-32; 2000b: 95-97; 2001: 63-71; 2004: 333-335, 346-347; Roese and Bondarenko 2003: 38-40), and only Benin showed that becoming a state is not the unique possibility for a chiefdom-based polity to escape disintegration by making an evolutionary step forward.
On the other hand, this type of organization was alternative to statehood, for it is clear that in many significant respects (economic, social, cultural) Benin was not less developed than the majority of the societies labeled as 'transitional early' (Claessen and Skalník 1978: 23, 589-593, 641) or 'archaic' (Feinman and Marcus 1998) states. In particular, the Benin megacommunity was not inferior to many states - societies in which bureaucracy is present, including the so-called 'transitional early states' characterized by the Early
State concept adepts as the ones in which territorial ('social') ties dominate over kin (Claessen and Skalnik 1978: 23, 589), and as one of which Benin is even sometimes attributed (Kochakova 1994), erroneously, as I believe I have managed to show above.
Thus, alternativity exists not only between heterarchic and ho-moarchic societies but also within the respective types (Bon-darenko 2001: 251-263; Bondarenko et al. 2003: 5-8). In particular, the early state, homoarchic by the very definition given by the concept's Founding Fathers - Claessen and Skalnik40, 'competes' not only with a variety of complex decentralized heterarchic sociopolitical systems (for examples see, e.g., contributions in Ehrenreich et al. 1995; Korotayev 1995; 1996; Thevenot 1996: Ch. 7; Possehl 1998; Schoenfelder 2003), but also with some forms of socio-political organization like megacommunity, not less complex, not less centralized, and not less homoarchic than the early state itself.
NOTES
* The author is grateful to Prof. David Small at Lehigh University (Bethlehem, PA, USA) for supplying him with a copy of Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies which is unavailable from Moscow libraries. My thanks also go to Mr. David Easterbrook due to whose friendly attitude I have repeatedly studied at the Melville J. Herskovits Library of African Studies, Northwestern University (Evanston, IL, USA), and to Prof. Alf Ludtke upon whose kind invitation I got access to the most recent academic literature in the libraries of the Max Planck Society Institute of History and University of Gottingen (Germany) in summer 2003.
1 Crumley (1995: 3) insists just on 'the addition of the term heterarchy to the vocabulary of power relations.' (my emphasis) and sees the prerequisite for heter-archic socio-political organization in the diversity of sources of power, as far as her concept is concentrated precisely on the society's political subsystem. Discussing the 'heterarchic state', Crumley in this respect does not differ from the majority of contemporary more traditionally' thinking theorists who 'argue that the evolution of social complexity needs to be understood first and foremost as a political process' (Earle 1994: 940) and also tend to look at the state, more or less exclusively, as a specific form of political organization (see below). However, Crumley does see power relations (heterarchic and otherwise) not as a thing in itself but in their interaction with, and dependence on the social, mental (values system), and ecological milieu and legitimately builds her concept on this base.
2 In the meantime, Pearson (2001) has recently attempted at employing both of the respective approaches - the heterarchy (but, of course, not heterarchy/homoarchy) and network/corporate strategies ones for a case study - of state formation on the Okinawa islands.
3 In particular, many (though not all [Schapera 1956: 208]) structuralists of the mid-20th century, being influenced by Radcliffe-Brown, tended to discredit the right to exercise coercive authority as a feature typical of state organization arguing that it characterizes any political system (Fortes and Evans-Pritchard 1940/1987: XIV f.; Mair 1965: 101-102). Marxists and neoevolutionists do not hesitate to assign 'ripe', not incipient coercion as a characteristic of the state only. For Marxists it is the core of their 'class approach' to the phenomenon (though in anthropology in general this idea is rooted owe to Max Weber's [1922/1947; 1978] concepts of 'political community' and 'legitimation of power' to a non less degree than due to the classics of Marxism's writings). Meanwhile neoevolution-ists disagree with each other whether already the origin of the state is rooted in coercion either or whether the pre-state was entering the historical stage as an all-benefiting institution which became coercive just at the very moment of transformation into 'true' state (the famous Fried - Service controversy).
4 If these characteristics are sufficient, is another point to which I will return below, in the course of the article.
5 For example, see the following definitions (my emphases): 'Chiefdoms are redistributional societies with a permanent central agency of coordination' (Service 1962/1971: 134); chiefdom is 'a polity that organizes centrally a regional population in the thousands' (Earle 1991: 1); '... a chiefdom is an aggregate of villages under the centralized rule of a paramount political leader. This is the basic structural nature of a chiefdom' (Carneiro 1998: 19); chiefdoms are 'societies with centralized but not internally specialized authority' (Spencer 1998: 5; following [Wright 1977: 381]). This is even more so in the case of complex chiefdom (e.g., Earle 1978: 173-185; Pauketat 1994; Johnson and Earle 2000: 301-303). As Timothy Earle resumes in his prominent review article (1987: 289), '... centrality is the clearest indicator of chiefdoms' (for general discussion of chiefdoms as centralized polities see Beliaev et al. 2001). Furthermore, even in simple societies power may be centralized by a 'big man' (Sahlins 1963) or a 'chieftain' who thus establishes '. centralized political leadership that operates from time to time among autonomous village societies but that is generally short-lived', so the term 'chieftain' '... designates explicitly the form of centralized leadership.' (Redmond 1998: 3). The variety of non-state centralized forms of societies and leadership types is by no means at all limited to those mentioned above.
6 A remarkable reformulation of his previous distinction between 'the decentralized stratified society' and 'centralized archaic state' (Kristiansen 1991: 19-21).
7 Symptomatically, Kristiansen remarks that 'Similar structures may develop in pastoral societies in their interaction with state societies. ' (1998: 46) while by now specialists in pastoral cultures have established a well-grounded tradition of assessing most complex pastoral, especially nomadic, societies as clearly and explicitly homoarchic (in my terms) explaining it just as an outcome of their interaction with agriculturalists' states (e.g., Barfield 1992; Khazanov 1994; Kradin 2003; for more detail see Kradin 2002). On the other hand, just those pastoral societies which were not involved into active interaction with autochthonous agricultural (or imposed colonial and post-colonial) states normally remained politically 'egalitarian' or 'tribal', as specialists (e.g., Irons 1994; Salzman 1999: 35-41)
point out. The changes in pastoral societies' systems of leadership under the state's pressure one can observe nowadays are also characteristic: introduction of private landownership reshapes them in the direction of homoarchization (see e.g., for the East African Maasai: Kituyi 1990; Horn 1998). It is also important to note with respect to Kristiansen's arguments that even the most complex pastoral societies are now not often regarded as states; rather they are viewed as very complex but nevertheless non-state societies (labeled by Kradin [e.g., 2000a: 279-282; 2000b: 296-299] as 'supercomplex chiefdoms'). Kristiansen writes that one of his intentions is to substitute for 'the decentralized archaic state' the notion of 'military democracy' (1998: 46). This is remarkable either: since the 19th century (Morgan 1877; Engels 1884/1985) the latter notion has been reserved by (neo)evolutionists and especially Marxists for complex heterarchic 'pre-state' societies (e.g.: Averkieva 1968; Khazanov 1968; Pershits 1986) including Bronze Age European (e.g.: Otto and Horst 1982; Bockisch 1987). So, here Kristiansen proves once again the irrelevance of his comparison of the European Bronze Age societies with the pastoral cultures he means, but what is much more important is that he exemplifies unwillingly that centralization and heterarchic social organization do not exclude each other though heterarchy may predict a lower degree of centralization than homoarchy does. Kristiansen's appeals to the pastoral comparative data and the notion of military democracy remained much more reasonable till the moment when he decided to substitute 'the decentralized stratified society' for 'decentralized archaic state'.
8 Note however, that implicitly the idea of professional administration as a distinctive feature of the state was influentially singled out in anthropology rather long before Weber, particularly by Morgan (1877; separation of power from the populace as the second of the state's three distinctive features) being then developed in his vein by Engels (1884/1985) and - already in the mid-20th century - by neoevolutionists and Marxists (mainly American and Soviet respectively).
9 Chronological problems are among most intricate in the study of Benin history. None of the dates prior to the European written sources appearance in the late 15th - 16th centuries and the majority of dates after that is more than conventional. In particular, on debates around the date of almost the most important event in Benin history, the change of the First dynasty by the Second (what entailed serious socio-anthropological consequences) see Bondarenko 2003a: 74-77.
10 For general descriptions and detailed analyses of the Benin titles system see: Read 1904; Egharevba 1956; 1960: 78-80; Bradbury 1957: 35-44; Roese 1988; 1993; Eweka, E. B. 1992; Bondarenko 1993a: 158-165; 1995a: 231-257; 2001: 212-229; Roese and Bondarenko 2003: 318-331. The last of these publication also see for comprehensive account of Benin history from the earliest times till the kingdom's conquest by the British in 1897, while the book by Bradbury remains unsurpassed in the field of the Bini historical ethnography.
11 I accept the 'general' definition of community given by Murdock and Wilson (1972: 255) who wrote:
We assume that there is and must be a unit of significant social interaction beyond the family. It follows that it is possible to identify this unit as the community for each society. The main
criteria for determining the community are: (1) it is the maximal number of people who normally reside together in face-to-face association; (2) the members interact with some regularity; (3) it is a significant focus of social identity for the members. . In general, we chose the unit that seemed to be the focus of the most significant regular interaction and identification.
Their 'specific' approach to defining the community in the political context 'as the lowest level of political integration' is also taken into account (Murdock and Wilson 1972: 256). In my view, the emphasis on the fact that 'autonomous communities' have never been truly autonomous but initially formed parts of wider systems of intercommunal interaction recently made by Stephen Kowalew-ski (2003), does not disregard the concept of community in general though may profitably shift researchers' attention from studying it 'as such' to doing it in a much more historical context, in light of its place in a broader cultural milieu. In fact, this discussion is an 'echo' of the furious debate which is in full swing in present-day archaeology: between the adherents of the approaches which can be labeled as world-system ('regional-interaction-based') and particularistic ('local-community-oriented') ones (see in particular, Kristiansen 1998 vs. Harding 2000). My belief is that these approaches do not contradict but rather compliment each other (compare with the debate between the world-system and civilization approaches adherents and its estimation by the present author: Bondarenko 2003b) and hence, as has just been argued, the concept of community still remains valid.
12 Oranmiyan's wife, the mother of the first Oba Eweka I, is said to be Bini. Bini is the biggest Edo-speaking ethnic group; the names 'Bini' and 'Edo' are quite often used as synonyms what is of course inexact.
13 Sigmund Freud (1911/1923: 63) showed a very keen insight by writing that taboo 'not only distinguishes kings and exalt them over all common mortals but also turns their life into unbearable torture and burden and inflicts on them chains of slavery much heavier than on their subjects'.
14 The episode Egharevba relates happened in the 1890s.
15 However, it must be stressed that what was sacralized were not concrete Obas as personalities but the very power and institution of the supreme ruler (Nkanta and Arinze n.d.: 5).
16 Just due to this in the situation when ancestors' cult was the central form of religion in Benin both at the local and uppermost levels of complexity, priesthood was never organized in a distinct, economically and politically influential corporation (Roth 1903/1968: 50; Sharevskaja 1957: 205; Dike 1959: 13; Kochakova 1986: 145-146, 151; Bondarenko 1995a: 270) like in supercomplex societies which religious systems, especially on the highest complexity level, concentrated on anthropomorphic deities or God (Egypt, Mesopotamia, medieval Europe, Aztecs, etc.; the most remarkable exception is the Islamic world where those called 'people of religion' cannot be regarded as priests proper). Though people for whom priestly responsibilities were primary could have existed since the First dynasty time (Egharevba 1960: 2), Benin priests performed either cults minor in their importance (see Roese and Reichel 1990: 390-391, 393-394) or assisted the Oba with his supreme priests duties' performance (e.g., Talbot 1926: II, 308;
Egharevba 1949: 30; 1956: 11; 1960: 11, 79-82; Bradbury 1957: 34, 40, 54, 55; 1959: 191; Palau Marti 1960: 79-80; Omijeh 1971: 118; Ayeni 1975: 38-47; Blackmun 1984: II, 366-369 et al.; Imoagene 1990: 22). In Benin people did not need professional mediators between them and venerated ancestors: the cult was personal, kin in nature and presupposed no supreme or esoteric knowledge inaccessible to all. In this society there was also no ideology, popular or official, for imposing of which professional priests could be instrumental. The hierarchy of mediators between a person and ancestors was not spiritual but purely social: a common Bini venerated the ancestors of his own, the head of a family or community - of all the respective units members, finally the Oba appeared in the role of the supreme priest as he, the father of all the country's citizens, performed rites of the cult of royal ancestors, hence the all now living Bini's forefathers. (However, it must be noted that one of the changes that accompanied the extension of communal matrix through chiefdom to the all-Benin level was that the sovereign could well be not the senior in his lineage. In this case his political seniority in the country looked more significant than his not that high position in his own kin group).
17 However, for Morgan (1877) (who is volens nolens a predecessor of all the subsequent theorists and a source of inspiration for not few of them) just this very aspect was of primary importance in comparison with the form of political organization as such.
18 In the Marxist theory the transition from kin to territorial ties has begun to serve as an essential precondition for social classes formation prior to what the rise of the state was declared impossible, as the state was seen as political organization predestined for guaranteeing the exploitative class' dominance in society. Particularly, Engels (1884/1985: 198-199) wrote:
As far as the state arose due to the need to keep in check the opposite of classes; as far as at the same time it arose in the very clashes of those classes, according to the general rule it is the state of the most powerful, economically dominant class which with the help of the state becomes the politically dominant class as well, and thus acquires new means for suppression and exploitation of the oppressed class.
Most rigidly this postulate was formulated by Lenin: 'The state appears where and when the division of society into classes appears' (1917/1974: 67). In fact, hardly not the main point of a Marxist social scientist's departure from the camp of 'orthodoxes' to that of 'creative Marxists' was his or her desire to reconcile this dogma with historical and ethnographic facts or even to overcome it. Particularly, in the West this led to the appearance of 'structural Marxism' with its tendency '... to reverse the causal relationship between base and superstructure.' (Sanderson 2003: 180), while in the Soviet Union the meaningless euphemism for the Early State, ranneklassovoe obshchestvo ('early-class society') was invented (see Bondarenko 1991). On the absence of social classes in the Marxist sense in Benin see: Kalous 1970; Kochakova 1986; Bondarenko 1995a.
19 These mid-20th century anthropologists provided conclusive arguments for the importance of territorial ties in primitive (non-state) cultures. As a result, already
in 1965 Lewis had good reasons to argue that 'The fundamentally territorial character of social and political association in general is indeed usually taken for granted, and has been assumed to apply as much to segmentary lineage societies as to other types of society' (Lewis 1965: 96). On the other hand, historians and anthropologists also showed that the typically non- and originally pre-state institutions of kinship could preserve some importance in state societies including medieval European (e.g., Bloch 1939-1940/1961: 141 ff.; Lewis 1965: 99-101; Genicot 1968; Duby 1970; Claessen and Skalnik 1978: 22, 589, 641; Korotayev and Obolonkov 1989; Tainter 1990: 29-30). In fact, it has eventually turned out that the 'kin vs. territory' problem is that of measure and not of almost complete presence or absence although the general socio-historical tendency is really towards gradual substitution of kin-based institutions by territory-based ones. Fried (1960/1970: 692-693) was very accurate indeed postulating that the state is organized not on a non-kin but 'supra-kin' basis.
20 But not always: the area giving probably the most important (in the historical long-run) exceptions to the rule is Europe, in some parts of which unilineal descent groups disappeared at early stages of history being substituted by nuclear family and neighbor (territorial) community. For example, in Greece it happened by the Dark Age time (Andreev 1976: 74-78; Frolov 1988: 79-80; on genos as not sib or clan in anthropological terms [Lowie 1920; Ember and Ember 1999: 349, 353] see: Smith, R. C. 1985: 53), in Latium before Rome was founded and royal authority in it established in the 8th century B.C. (e.g., Dozhdev 2004; see here also the criticism on the concept of gens as clan) and in Scandinavia by the close of the Bronze Age after in this sense transitory period (from about 2600 B.C.) of the lineage and extended family dominance (Earle 1997: 25-26, 163; Anderson, C. E. 1999: 14-15). This paved the way to the territorial organization's formation prior to that of well-developed bureaucratic apparatus (Kristiansen 1998: 45, 46) and generally speaking, contributed significantly to the 'European phenomenon', 'European miracle' - the modern European civilization's appearance. Korotayev (2003; 2004: 89-107, 119-137) has demonstrated convincingly that 'deep Christianization' promotes the rise of communal (and, in the long run, supracommunal) democracy by crushing the unilineal descent organization (alongside with a number of other potentially democratizing innovations like insistence on monogamy [Korotayev and Bondarenko 2000]). I think the reverse statement could also be true: deep Christianization is easier achieved in the social milieu characterized by absence or weakening of unilineal descent organization. Note also that Christianity is heavily rooted in the ancient Jewish monotheism while the Old Testament prophets entered the stage and started teaching in the situation of the sib organization's gradual weakening (though not disappearance) after the Israelite Kingdom's formation (Nikol'skij 1914: 385-415; Jakobson 1997: 351-369). It is also reasonable to suppose that first, that was really weakening of the unilineal descent organization and not the territorial organization's formation as such what contributed to the 'European miracle''s birth, and second, territorial organization is nevertheless an independent variable. Both of these propositions are proved by the late ancient - modern West and Central Asian, North African, and even modern European politically democratic tribal cultures in which one can observe territorial division, unilineal descent including clan (sib)
organization, and non-Christian (nowadays predominantly Muslim) religion at one time (e.g., Evans-Pritchard 1949; Whitaker 1968; Irons 1975; Korotayev 1990). The second proposition is also confirmed, for instance, by North American evidence from tribal societies with distinctive unilineal descent groups (e.g., Morgan 1851; Lowie 1935; Drager 1968). Finishing one of his recent articles, Yuri Berezkin (2000: 223) asks the reader: 'Would it be too bold to suggest that it was. lack of, or underdevelopment of, a clan-and-moiety system that contributed to the more important role of personality that, in turn, had hindered the development of hierarchies?' Indeed, it would not.
21 As Allen Johnson and Timothy Earle (2000: 304) put it,
Whereas chiefdoms vest leadership in generalized regional institutions, in states the increased scope of integration requires specialized regional institutions to perform the tasks of control and management. ... Along with this increasing elaboration of the ruling apparatus comes increasing stratification. Elites are now unrelated by kinship to the populations they govern.
22 In particular, such significant for the development of anthropological thought theories as those of evolutionists (from Maine to Engels), of the French sociological (Durkheim, Mauss) and British structuralist (Evans-Pritchard, Fortes, Mair, etc.) schools, of substantivists in economic anthropology beginning with Polanyi, are based (see Earle 1994: 947) on understanding of societal forms, including the state, which involves both political and socio-economic characteristics. Famous and still influential neoevolutionist concepts (Sahlins 1960; Service 1962/1971; 1975; Fried 1967; Carneiro 1970) also derive, more or less openly, from this premise. In the meantime, for instance, the Archaic State concept elaborated recently by a group of archaeologists headed by Gary Feinman and Joyce Marcus does limit the notion of the state to a kind of political organization as the state is seen by them merely '. as a political or governmental unit.' (Marcus and Feinman 1998: 4). The same is true with the Early State concept (Claessen and Skalník 1978). Having eventually been developed into a truly organic combination of evolutionist and structuralist postulates (Claessen 2000), it nevertheless also reduces the notion of the state to its political aspect (see Kradin 1991: 283; Bondarenko 1998b: 19; 2001: 243-244; Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000c: 14-15) what could give reason to some of its adherents to designate Benin as an early state (e.g., Kochakova 1986, 1996b; Shifferd 1987) precisely due to the fact that this concept not only reduces the state to a specific system of political institutions but also rightly recognizes that as a rule the political subsystem develops towards the state more rapidly than the socio-economic one. However, characterization of Benin as belonging to the highest type of the early state - 'transitional' is improper in any case (see below). Besides, it must not but be noted that though the Early State concept is still most well-known and best developed in its initial modification, its main proponent, Henri Claessen in one of his latest publications (2003: 161) declares openly that 'A state is a specific kind of social organization, expressing a specific type of social order in a society' (my emphasis). Precisely this vision (which also naturally presupposes the political aspect of social system's embracing) coinsides completely with that of the present author's and testifies to what in fact the whole history of the Early State concept does: that this valuable
concept possesses a considerable potential for further elaboration and correction, what its adherents with Claessen in the head are doing quite successfully for already over a quarter of a century (on the concept's history, evolution, and prospects see Oosten and van de Velde 1994; Kochakova 1996a, 1999; Bondarenko 1998b; Kradin 1998).
23 In his recent critical reevaluation of his own (and Claessen's) Early State concept Peter Skalnik (2002: 6) recognizes explicitly that 'the early state in a number of concrete cases but also by its theory of inchoate (incipient) state, "swallowed" chiefdom as an independent category'.
24 In particular, Claessen and Skalnik (1978: 593) attribute as transitional early states the following societies from their sample: China (late 2nd - early 1st millennia B.C.), Maurya (4th - 2nd centuries B.C.), France (10th - 11th centuries), Aztecs (15th - 16th centuries), Kuba (19th century), and Jimma (19th - 20th centuries [till 1932]).
25 In the Claessen and Skalnik's sample (1978: 593) the limited state (the typical early state in their own thesaurus) is represented by Egypt (first half of the 1st millennium B.C.), Scythia (6th - 3rd centuries B.C.), Iberia (6th century B.C. - 1st century A.D.), Axum (1st - 6th centuries), Angkor (9th - 13th centuries), Mongolia (13th - 14th centuries), Incas (15th - 16th centuries), Kachari (17th - 18th centuries), and Yoruba (19th century). To these, for example, the Polish state of the 9th - 11th centuries was added by Tymowski (1996). For 'the inchoate early state' which I cannot regard as state in any sense at all, Claessen and Skalnik (1978: 589) postulate not only kinship ties domination but also 'a limited existence of full-time specialists...' that are thus 'rare' in such societies (1978: 23), i.e., do not form the objectively absolutely necessary and hence non-removable core of the government. At this point, it is also worth noting Aidan Southall's (2000: 150) remark: 'Claessen and Skalnik (1978) distinguished inchoate, typical and transitional early states. The segmentary state conforms most nearly to the inchoate state, but Claessen considered the segmentary state as I defined it not a state at all'. Hence, in my turn, I would not label the societies Southall means as states even more so. In fact, the cultures fitting Southall's segmentary state model (1956, 1988, 1999) might be regarded as typological predecessors of societies like Benin. In Benin ritual suzerainty of the sovereign also exceeded his abilities to control the country's periphery in practical terms (see Bondarenko 2001: 183-184) but the crucial difference between say, 'Southall's' Alur and Benin was that within the former the component units could exercise legitimate force and even secede from the wider polity to join another while in the Benin case all this was impossible, at least within 'Benin proper' - the political and ethno-cultural core of the Benin 'Empire' of the mid-15 - 19th centuries. The degree of centralization in Benin was significantly, qualitatively higher than in the Alur society.
26 I.e., the communities which did not form parts of any chiefdom within the Benin Kingdom.
27 Maisels denotes sibs/clans as 'lineages' or 'conical clans' (e.g., Chinese) while lineages proper he calls 'minimal lineages'.
28 In fact, Trigger (1993) explicitly discusses Benin together with neighboring historically and culturally related to her 'Yoruba city-states'.
29 Thus at this level of analysis it is incorrect to equate the Sumerian e and Akkadian bitum with the Greek oikos as Maisels (following Gelb [1979: 12-13])
does, paying no attention to the difference between the two types of households I emphasize. Mesopotamian households clearly are of the second type distinguished by me what becomes evident from Maisels's own description above all, while the oikos was individual families uniting household as back as in the Dark Ages (Andreev 1976: 74-78; Frolov 1988: 79-80) which later could unite for political and economic reasons in artificial kinship units called gene (Fine 1983: 35-36). Watson's (1978: 156) reasoning (cited by Maisels [1987: 350]) that already in the 6th millennium B.C. Near East '. the basic residential unit. was. a nuclear family.' (see also Byrd 2000) does not discredit what has been argued just above: in anthropological terms, this only means that not 'joint' ('large') but 'small' extended family was the typical residential unit. However, in more essential respects - economic, social, and political, extended families had clear priority over their nuclear parts (see, e.g., Diakonoff 1985; Diakonoff et al. 1989: 57-72).
30 Characteristically, Dmitri Dozhdev, criticizing the traditional view on institutional evolution of early Rome in light of the sib/clan theory, writes in introduction to his article (2004: 389) as follows:
The below picture of the formation of the Roman state, the suggested legal evaluations and the attempt to find out a continuous line that determines its specific features as a version of the political development are based on the recognition of the civil community (civitas) as the phenomenological and conceptual kernel of the problem. Rome was founded in the urban epoch.
31 Among such rare cases there are medieval Thailand, Laos, and the Malabar Coast of India (Alaev 2000: 129).
32 In the ancient world, for instance, Sumer gave examples of communities of both types: with kin and with non-kin extended families forming them (Chipirova 1988: 7).
33 Treating multiple in Benin art compositions with Oba in the center flanked by dignitaries depicted smaller than the sovereign is as 'a classic hierarchical composition', Herbert Cole (1981: 12) rightly pointed out '. its great value in Benin thought, not only as a socio-political statement, but as a spiritual, mythic, and psychological metaphor as well'.
34 Indeed, this does not mean the community's disappearance (see above). The same is true with such other basically non-state social units as, for example, lineages. However, within the state structure they, being in essence non-bureaucratic (as well as communities) cannot and do not form the matrix for the uppermost level institutions' building up as lineage norms (loyalty to lineage members) are incompatible with state norms (Fallers 1956: 12 f, 277 f; see also, e.g., Lewis's [1965: 100] compressed but instructive characteristics of the Zulu and Southeast Chinese socio-political systems based on works by Gluckman [1940] and Freed-man [1958]). As for communities, they usually decay only in the process of the wider society's transition to capitalism (as well as early institutions of kinship [Parsons 1960; 1966]). Examples of the community's disappearance in agricultural societies are seldom, Egypt from the Middle Kingdom on being the most prominent one (Diakonoff et al. 1989: I, 143; Diakonoff and Jakobson 1998: 26-27). However, even there 'it is possible. that the ancient Egyptian peasantry, which for the most part seems to have continued to live in traditional villages long after
the Old Kingdom, may have preserved significant aspects of communal social life.' (Trigger 1985: 59). Besides, '. probably in some respect whole Egypt was considered as a community with the pharao as its leader, and as not a neigbor [community] but a kin one.' (Diakonoff and Jakobson 1998: 27; see also McNeill 1963: 72).
35 Just its stability permits extrapolation of ethnographic evidence on earlier periods of the Bini social history with high degree of plausibility. Robert Bradbury, the greatest classic of ethnographic and historical anthropological Benin studies, especially made this point (Bradbury 1964).
36 The most vivid example of complex society based on the neighbor community matrix is given by the ancient Greek polis. It also shows that no state can be based on the community matrix of any kind: just because no community permits the existence of bureaucracy, the polis was lacking it either, and hence was not state (e.g., Berent 2000; Marcus and Feinman [1998: 8] remark correctly that '. many Aegean specialists do not believe the polis was a state at all.'). Even tyranny never changed this situation and in fact, served a temporal means for further strengthening of those fundamental heterarchic features of the polis when they were challenged this or that way. Not by chance tyrannies were not long-lived and left the historical stage as soon as they fulfilled their mission (e.g., Andrewes 1956; Mosse 1969; Vliet 1987; Tumans 2002: 285-369). In his review of the 2nd edition of Murray's 'Early Greece' (1993) Karpjuk points out that 'in the author's opinion, the reason for the appearance of tyrannic regimes in Archaic Greece was the demos' need in leaders for the sruggle with aristocracy, who due to this acquired such great importance in this transitional period', and then remarks that 'Murrey's viewpoint on the reasons of appearance and social roots of tyranny is quite traditional' (Karpjuk 1994: 193, 194). Indeed, in some cases, Athens being most important, those were just tyrants who paved the way from aristocratic political regime 'to government by the demos, democracy' (Finley 1981: 104). (The latter as political regime exemplifying 'the ideal representation of a power heterarchy' [Crumley 1995: 3; emphasis in the original; see also Vliet 2003] nevertheless must not be identified with heterarchy as a social system: in particular, the unavoidably heterarchic polis social framework admitted not only democratic but also aristocratic and oligarchic political forms). Bouzek (1990: 172) is right both in his irony about endless academic debates and in representation of the Greeks' own distinction between their poleis and other peoples' states: 'The Greeks had fewer problems than we have with the definition of the state. They saw kingdoms and kings in all parts of the world where they met one ruler, and not the council of a polis or ethnos'. However, in the anthropological perspective the problem with attribution of the polis as the state is not in the fact that typically it is not a monarchy (indeed, we do know a great number of republican states, for example, modern) but in the fact that the Greek polis (on the contrary to the Roman civitas' at transition from Republic to Empire [Hopkins 1968; Shtaerman 1989; Blois 1994]) never gave rise to bureaucracy which (besides many other deeds) could divide the polity's territory arbitrarily, ignoring the natural division which had resulted from local communities' synoecism as the most frequent means for the polis' very formation. Furthermore, for Greeks the polis was not a political or territorial unit first and foremost but a self-governing (i.e., never bureaucracy-governed!) collectivity
of equal in rights citizens (e.g., Finley 1963: 56; 1982: 3-4; Hansen 1991: 58-59; Strogetskij 1995). Attempts to avoid these facts and substantiate the viewpoint at the polis as a 'non-bureaucratic state' (e.g., Vliet 1987, 1994, 2003; for the most recent one see Grinin 2004; note that Grinin's attempt to avoid professional fulltime administration as state's feature sine qua non disavows his own definition of the state given elsewhere [1997: 20; 2000: 190] in which this point presents) seem to contradict the well-grounded idea of the state's intimate relatedness to the presence of bureaucracy. In the meantime, the recognition of the polis as a non-state system does not lead to the conclusion that the state cannot be democratic or non-monarchical (what, for example, Grinin actually erroneously equates with democracy). First, at least today in many countries, mainly in the West but not only there, one can observe both democracy and bureaucracy. Second, though it goes without saying that monarchy is the most wide-spread form of political regime in pre-industrial state societies (see Claessen and Skalnik 1978: 535-596), history has seen instances of non-monarchical bureaucracies yet in ancient and medieval times. For example, in oligarchic Venice from 1297 and till Napoleon's occupation in 1797 Great Council consisting of adult males of specified elite families selected and elected among its members functionaries including the head of polity (doge) without any feedback from the populace. In fact, from the viewpoint of society as a whole, that was appointment by a small group of people, only to which the appointees were responsible. Due to this they functioned as bureaucrats in many respects pointed out by Weber (see, e.g., Romano 1987; Zannini 1993). In contrast, even in so-called oligarchic poleis the whole collectivity of citizens remained the administrators' (magistrates') elector at least in principle, though like in Venice and contrary to democratic poleis, not all the citizens were eligible for being elected. To be sure: in oligarchic poleis the circle of competent citizens was narrower than in democratic and only those belonging to an even narrower circle -oligarchy, could be elected. But oligarchs did not elect magistrates themselves like the Venice Great Council members did. Magistrates were elected by citizens of the oligarchs number (Jajlenko 1983: 165-173). The polis also should not be considered as a case when transition from (mainly) kin-based to (predominantly) non-kin social division outstrips the formation of bureaucracy, as first, there was no such a transition because it was inherited from the preceding incipient simple society (e.g., Andreev 1976; Frolov 1988) and second, bureaucracy never formed in poleis prior to their integration into the Macedonian empire and the kingdoms which appeared on Alexander the Great power's debris, when bureaucracy was just imposed on poleis. Nevertheless they mainly preserved internal autonomy and typical non-bureaucratic system of government as a means of its realization and thorough support (e.g., Bikerman 1938/1985: 131-135; Allen 1983: 75, 109 et al.; Diakonoff et al. 1989: II, 322-330, 324-345). All in all, it is not so surprising that the polis is rarely considered in general works on social evolution (Blanton et al. 1996: 2; Marcus and Feinman 1998: 8-9), especially in those written by the scholars thinking within the unilinear typology paradigm.
37 The same as non-monarchical form of government does not inevitably predict a society's non-state nature (see note 31).
38 Besides, every person was believed to have four soles that demonstrated different degree of separateness from his or her physical membrane (Bradbury 1973: 271-282).
39 As a megacommunity I shall also designate, for instance, the Bamum Kingdom of the late 16th/early 17th - 19th centuries in present-day Cameroon which as a whole represented an extension up to the supercomplex level of the lineage principles and organization forms, so the society acquired the shape of 'maximal lineage' (Tardits 1980). Outside Africa megacommunities may be recognized in Indian societies of the late 1st millennium B.C. - first centuries A.D. Naturally, differing in many respects from the Benin pattern, they nevertheless fit the main distinctive feature of megacommunity as social type: integration of a supercom-plex (exceeding the complex chiefdom level) society on community (and hence non-state) basis. In particular, Samozvantsev (2001) describes those societies as permeated by communal orders notwithstanding the difference in socio-political organization forms. 'The principle of communality', he argues, was the most important factor of social organization in India during that period. In the south of India this situation lasted much longer, till the time of the Vijayanagara Empire -the mid-14th century (Palat 1987; Stein, B. 1989). A number of other examples of supercomplex societies in which 'the supracommunal political structure was shaped according to the community type' (similar to the Bini type) is provided by the 1st millennium A.D. Southeast Asia - by such societies as e.g., Funan and possibly (see Mudar 1999) Dvaravati (Rebrikova 1987: 159-163). Apart from all the rest, these examples show that megacommunity may be seen among not only 'city-based' societies like Benin, but among 'territorial' ones as well.
40 The definition they give is the following one:
The early state is a centralized socio-political organization for the regulation of social relations in a complex, stratified society divided into at least two basic strata, or emergent social classes - viz. the rulers and the ruled - whose relations are characterized by political dominance of the former and tributary obligations of the latter, legitimized by a common ideology of which reciprocity is the basic principle (Claessen and Skalnik 1978: 640; see also pp. 533-596, 637-650).
Note that the homoarchic character of the early state is also stressed e.g., in its such heavily criticized but still influential 'classical' concepts as those of El-man Service (1962/1971; 1975), Morton Fried (1960/1970; 1967), and Robert Carneiro (1970), notwithstanding the significant difference in those scholars' general theoretical premises: seeing the state power as basically either consensual or coercive.
REFERENCES
Abeles, M.
2000. Etat. In Bonte, P., and Izard, M. (eds.), Dictionnaire de leth-nologie et de tanthropologie (pp. 239-242). Paris: Quadrige/Presses Universitaires de France. Adams, J.
1823. Remarks on the Country Extending from Cape Palmas to the River Congo. London: Whittaker.
Agbontaen, K. A.
1995. Art, Power Politics, and the Interrelatedness of Social Classes in Pre-colonial Benin. Saint Petersburg Journal of African Studies 4: 118-124.
Ahanmisi, O.
1992. Strength in Weakness: Bini Women in Affinal Relations. Ph. D. dissertation. Lund: Lund University. Ajisafe, A. K.
1945. Laws and Customs of the Benin People. Lagos: Kash and Klare Bookshop.
Akenzua, S. I. A.
1974. Foreword. In Ogbobine 1974: 3-5. Alaev, L. B.
2000. L. B. Alaev: obshchina v ego zhizni. Istorija neskolkikh nauch-nykh idej v dokumentakh i materialakh [L. B. Alaev: Community in His Life. History of Several Scientific Ideas in Documents and Materials]. Moscow: Vostochnaja literartura.
Alexeev, I. L., Beliaev, D. D., and Bondarenko, D. M. (eds.) 2004. Third International Conference 'Hierarchy and Power in the History of Civilizations'. Abstracts. Moscow: Center for Civilization and Regional Studies Press and Institute for African Studies Press.
Allen, R. E.
1983. The Attalid Kingdom: A Constitutional History. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Anderson, C. E.
1999. Formation and Resolution of Ideological Contrast in the Early History of Scandinavia. Ph. D. dissertation. Cambridge: University of Cambridge.
Anderson, D. G.
1994. The Savannah River Chiefdoms. Tuscaloosa, AL: University of Alabama Press.
Andreev, Yu. V.
1976. Rannegrecheskij polis (gomerovskij period) [Early Greek Polis (The Dark Age Period)]. Leningrad: Leningrad State University Press. Andrewes, A.
1956. The Greek Tyrants. London: Hutchinson. Armstrong, R. G.
1960. The Development of Kingdoms in Negro Africa. Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria 2: 27-39.
Astley, Th. (publ.)
1746. An Account of the Kingdom of Benin. In Astley, Th. (publ.),
A New General Collection of Voyages and Travels; Consisting of the
Most Esteemed Relations, Which Have Been Hitherto Published in Any Language; Comprehending Everything Remarkable in Its Kind, in Europe, Asia, Africa, and America. Vol. 3 (pp. 88-105). London: Astley.
Averkieva, Yu. P.
1968. On the Role of Military Democracy in the History of Society. Moscow: Nauka.
Ayeni, P. M. (ed.)
1975. Festivals of Bendel State, Nigeria. Benin City: Ministry of Home Affairs and Information.
Baines, J., and Yoffee, N.
1998. Order, Legitimacy, and Wealth in Ancient Egypt and Mesopotamia. In Feinman and Marcus 1998: 199-260.
Barfield, Th. J.
1992. The Perilous Frontier: Nomadic Empires and China, 221 B.C. to A.D. 1757. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Barry, H., III
2004. Heterarchical or Homoarchical Leadership and Kinship in Communities. In Alexeev, Beliaev, and Bondarenko 2004: 8-9.
Baum, R.
2004. Ritual and Rationality: Religious Roots of the Bureaucratic State in Ancient China. Social Evolution and History 3 (1): 41-68.
Beier, U.
1980. YorubaMyths. Cambridge etc.: Cambridge University Press.
Beliaev, D. D.
2000. Early State in the Classic Maya Lowlands: Epigraphic and Archaeological Evidence. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 188-195.
Beliaev, D. D., Bondarenko, D. M., and Korotayev, A. V.
2001. Origins and Evolution of Chiefdoms. Reviews in Anthropology 30: 373-395.
Belkov, P. L.
1995. Rannee gosudarstvo, predgosudarstvo, protogosudarstvo: igra v terminy? [Early State, Pre-state, Proto-state: Terms Game?] In Popov, V. A. (ed.), Rannie formy politicheskoj organizatsii: ot pervo-bytnosti k gosudarstvennosti [Early Forms of Political Organization: From Primitivity to Statehood] (pp. 165-187). Moscow: Nauka.
Berent, M.
2000. The Stateless Polis: The Early State and the Ancient Greek Community. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 225-241.
Berezkin, Yu. E.
2000. Once Again on Horizontal and Vertical Links in Structure of the Middle Range Societies. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 220-224.
Berreman, G. D.
1981. Social Inequality: A Cross-Cultural Analysis. In Berreman, G. D. (ed.), Social Inequality: Comparative and Developmental Approaches (pp. 3-40). New York: Academic Press. Bikerman, E.
1938/1985. Gosudarstvo Selevkidov [Institutions of the Seleucides]. Moscow: Nauka. Bindloss, H.
1898/1968. In the Niger Country. London: Cass. Blackmun, B. W.
1984. The Iconography of Carved Altar Tusks from Benin, Nigeria. Vols 1-3. Ph. D. dissertation. Los Angeles: University of California. Blanton, R. E.
1994. Houses and Households: A Comparative Study. New York: Plenum Press.
1995. The Cultural Foundations of Inequality in Households. In Price, T. D., and Feinman, G. M. (eds.), Foundations of Social Inequality (pp. 105-128). New York: Plenum Press.
1998. Beyond Centralization: Steps Toward a Theory of Egalitarian Behavior in Archaic States. In Feinman and Marcus 1998: 135-172.
Blanton, R. E., Feinman, G. M., Kowalewski, S. A., and Nicholas, L. M.
1999. Ancient Oaxaca. The Monte Alban State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Blanton, R. E., Feinman, G. M., Kowalewski, S. A., and Peregrine, P. N.
1996. A Dual-Processual Theory for the Evolution of Mesoamerican Civilization. Current Anthropology 37: 1-14.
Bloch, M.
1939-1940/1961. Feudal Society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Blois, L. de
1994. Problems of Scale as an Agent of Change in the Late Roman Republic. In van Bakel, M., Hagesteijn, R., and van de Velde, P. (eds.),
Pivot Politics. Changing Cultural Identities in Early State Formation Processes (pp. 121-129). Amsterdam: Het Spinhuis.
Bockisch, G.
1987. Heroenzeit und militärische Demokratie. Klio 69: 374-387.
Boisragon, A.
1898. The Benin Massacre. London: Methuen and Co.
Bondarenko, D. M.
1989. K voprosu o sootnoshenii klassogeneza i politogeneza v prot-sesse stanovlenija gosudarstva [On the Problem of Correlation of Social and Political Processes in State Formation]. In Gromyko, An. A. (ed.), Pjataja Vsesojuznaja konferentsija afrikanistov [The Fifth All-Union Conference of Africanists]. Vol. 2 (pp. 108-111). Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
1991. Vozniknovenie klassov i gosudarstva i nekotorye osobennosti ikh funktsionirovanija v dokapitalisticheskikh obshchestvakh [Classes and State Formation and Some Specific Features of Their Functioning in Pre-capitalist Societies]. In Truevtsev, K. M. (ed.), Kontseptsii obshchest-vennogo progressa. Tochka zrenija afrikanistov [Concepts of Social Progress. The Africanists' Viewpoint] (pp. 141-165). Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
1993a. Privilegirovannye kategorii naselenija v Benine nakanune pervykh kontaktov s evropejtsami [Privileged Categories of the Benin Population on the Eve of the First Contacts with Europeans]. In Popov, V. A. (ed.), Rannie formy sotsialnoj stratifkatsii: genezis, is-toricheskaja dinamika, potestarno-politicheskie funktsii [Early Forms of Social Stratification: Genesis, Historical Dynamics, Potestal-and-Political Functions] (pp. 145-168). Moscow: Nauka.
1993b. Stanovlenie gosudarstvennogo obshchestva. Pervyj vyzov vechnoj probleme v postsovetskoj etnologii [State Society Formation. The First Challenge to Eternal Problem in Post-Soviet Ethnology]. Vos-tok/Oriens 5: 185-197.
1994. Precolonial Benin: Personality, Authority and the Structure of Society. In Sabloff, J. A., and Lal, Makhan (eds.), State, City and Society (pp. 1-10). New Delhi: World Archaeological Congress-3.
1995a. Benin nakanune pervykh kontaktov s evropejtsami: chelovek, obshchestvo, vlast' [Benin on the Eve of the First Contacts with Europeans: Personality, Society, Authority]. Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
1995b. Megacommunity as a Variant of Structure and Type of Society: Precolonial Benin. In Kradin, N. N., and Lynsha, V. A. (eds.), Alternative Pathways to Early Statehood (pp. 100-108). Vladivostok: Dal'nauka.
1995c. Vozhdestva v dokolonial'nom Benine [Chiefdoms in Precolonial Benin]. In Popov, V. A. (ed.), Rannie formy politicheskoj organi-zatsii: ot pervobytnosti k gosudarstvennosti [Early Forms of Political Organization: From Primitivity to Statehood] (pp. 140-152). Moscow: Vostochnaja literatura.
1996a. Afrika: obshchestva, kul'tury, jazyki. Stanovlenie gosudarstva i ego al'ternativy [Africa: Societies, Cultures, Languages. State Formation and Its Alternatives]. Vostok/Oriens 5: 163-167.
1996b. Megaobshchina kak variant struktury i tipa sotsiuma: predpo-sylki slozhenija i funktsionirovanija [Megacommunity as a Variant of Structure and Type of Society: Preconditions of Emergence and Functioning]. Vostok/Oriens 3: 30-38.
1997a. Krugi afrikanskogo mirozdanija (po materialam edoja-zychnykh narodov Juzhnoj Nigerii) [Circles of the African Universe (By the Edo-speaking Peoples of Southern Nigeria Evidence)]. In Ksenofon-tova, N. A. (ed.), Mir afrikanskoj derevni. Dinamika razvitija sotsialnykh struktur i dukhovnaja kuttura [The World of African Village. Social Structure and Dynamics of Culture] (pp. 92-126). Moscow: Vostochnaja literatura.
1997b. Teorija tsivilizatsij i dinamika istoricheskogo protsessa v dokolonial'noj Tropicheskoj Afrike [Civilizations Theory and the Historical Process Dynamics in Pre-colonial Tropical Africa]. Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
1998a. 'Homologous Series' of Social Evolution. In Butovskaya, M., Korotayev, A., and Khristoforova, O. (eds.), Sociobiology of Ritual and Group Identity: A Homology of Animal and Human Behaviour. Concepts of Humans and Behaviour Patterns in the Cultures of the East and the West: Interdisciplinary Approach (pp. 98-99). Moscow: Russian State University for the Humanities Press.
1998b. Kontseptsija 'rannego gosudarstva': osnovnye polozhenija i popytka ikh otsenki [The 'Early State' Concept: Basic Tenets and an Attempt of Their Assessment]. In Sledzevski, I. V., and Bondarenko, D. M. (eds.), Afrika: obshchestva, kultury, jazyki [Africa: Societies, Cultures, Languages] (pp. 16-26). Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
1998c. Mnogolinejnost' sotsial'noj evoljutsii i al'ternativy gosudarstvu [The Multilinearity of Social Evolution and Alternatives to the State]. Vostok/Oriens 1: 195-202.
1998d. The Benin Kingdom (13th -19th Centuries) as a Megacommunity. In Butovskaya, M., Korotayev, A., and Khristoforova, O. (eds.), So-ciobiology of Ritual and Group Identity: A Homology of Animal and Human Behaviour. Concepts of Humans and Behaviour Patterns in the Cultures of the East and the West: Interdisciplinary Approach (pp. 111-113). Moscow: Russian State University for the Humanities Press.
1999. The Rise of Chiefdoms and Urbanization Process among the Edo (Late 1st - Early 2nd Millennia A.D.). In Sledzevski, I. V., and Bondarenko, D. M. (eds.), Afrika: obshchestva, kul'tury, jazyki (Traditsionnyj i sovremennyj gorod v Afrike) [Africa: Societies, Cultures, Languages
(The Traditional and Modern African City)] (pp. 23-32). Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
2000a. Ancestors Cult and Power in the Traditional Bini Culture (Nigeria). In Orla-Bukowska, A.-M., Kowalski, K., Kubica-Heller, G., and Golonka-Czajkowska, M. (eds.), Crossing Categorical Boundaries: Religion as Politics / Politics as Religion. Book of Abstracts. 6th Biennial European Association of Social Anthropologists Conference (pp. 191192). Krakow: Jagiellonian University.
2000b. Benin (1st Millennium B.C. - 19th Century A.D.). In Bon-darenko and Korotayev 2000a: 87-127.
2000c. 'Homologous Series' of Social Evolution and Alternatives to the State in World History. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 213-219.
2000d. Obshchina i organizatsija zemledel'cheskogo proizvodstva v dokolonial'nom Benine [Community and Organization of Agricultural Production in Pre-colonial Benin]. In Popov, V. A. (ed.), Rannie formy sotsialnoj organizatsii. Genezis, funksionirovanie, istoricheskaja di-namika [Early Forms of Social Organization. Genesis, Functioning, Historical Dynamics] (pp. 93-108). Saint Petersburg: Museum of Anthropology and Ethnography Press.
2000e. Vlast' v obshchestvennom soznanii i politicheskaja boiba v Benine (XIII - XVI vv.) [Power in Mass Consciousness and Political Struggle in Benin (13th - 16th Centuries)]. In Vassiliev, L. S. (ed.), Politicheskaja intriga na Vostoke [Political Intrigue in the East] (pp. 327-350). Moscow: Vostochnaja literatura.
2001. Doimperskij Benin: formirovanie i evoljutsija sistemy sot-sial'no-politicheskikh institutov [Pre-imperial Benin: Formation and Evolution of the Sociopolitical Institutions System]. Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
2002. Kingdom without State? (Max Weber on Bureaucracy, and the 13th - 19th Centuries Benin). In Vassiliev, A. M. (ed.), African Studies in Russia 1998 - 2000 (pp. 54-60). Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
2003a. Advent of the Second (Oba) Dynasty: Another Assessment of a Benin History Key Point. History in Africa 30: 63-85.
2003b. Globalization vs. Dialogue of Civilizations: The World-System and Civilizational Approaches to History and Present. In 'Ouda, M. (ed.), Globalization and the Dialogue of Civilizations: Making of a New World (pp. 5-11). Cairo: Ain Shams University Press.
2004. From Local Communities to Megacommunity: Biniland in the 1st Millennium B.C. - 19th Century A.D. In Grinin, Carneiro, Bondarenko, Kradin, and Korotayev 2004: 325-363.
Bondarenko, D. M., and Crumley, C. L.
2004. Alternativity in Cultural History: Heterarchy and Homoarchy as Evolutionary Trajectories. In Alexeev, Beliaev, and Bondarenko 2004: 5.
Bondarenko, D. M., Grinin, L. E., and Korotayev, A. V.
2002. Alternative Pathways of Social Evolution. Social Evolution and History 1 (1): 54-79.
Bondarenko, D. M., and Korotayev, A. V. (eds.)
2000a. Civilizational Models of Politogenesis. Moscow: Center for Civilization and Regional Studies Press.
Bondarenko, D. M., and Korotayev, A. V.
2000b. Family Size and Community Organization: A Cross-Cultural Comparison. Cross-CulturalResearch 34: 152-189.
2000c. Introduction. In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a: 5-31.
Bondarenko, D. M., Korotayev, A. V., and Kradin, N. N.
2003. Introduction: Social Evolution, Alternatives, and Nomadism. In Kradin, N. N., Bondarenko, D. M., and Barfield, T. J. (eds.), Nomadic Pathways in Social Evolution (pp. 1-24). Moscow: Center for Civilization and Regional Studies Press.
Bondarenko, D. M., and. Roese, P. M.
1998. Pre-dynastic Edo: The Independent Local Community Government System and Socio-political Evolution. EthnographischArchäologische Zeitschrift 39: 367-372.
Bouzek, J.
1990. Studies of Greek Pottery in the Black Sea Area. Prague: Charles University.
Bradbury, R. E.
1957. The Benin Kingdom and the Edo-speaking Peoples of Southwestern Nigeria. London: International African Institute Press.
1959. Divine Kingship in Benin. Nigeria Magazine 62: 186-207.
1964. The Historical Uses of Comparative Ethnography with Special Reference to Benin and the Yoruba. In Vansina, J., Mauny, R., and Thomas, L. V. (eds.), The Historian in Tropical Africa (pp. 145-164). London etc.: Oxford University Press.
1969. Patrimonialism and Gerontocracy in Benin Political Culture. In Douglas, M., and Kaberry, Ph. M. (eds.), Man in Africa (pp. 17-36). London etc.: Tavistock.
1973. Benin Studies. London etc.: Oxford University Press.
Brumfiel, E. M.
1995. Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies: Comments. In Ehrenreich, Crumley, and Levy 1995: 125-131.
Butinov, N. A.
1967. Etnograficheskie materialy i ikh rol' v izuchenii obshchiny drevnego mira [Ethnographic Evidence and Its Role in the Study of Ancient Community]. In Its, R. F. (ed.), Obshchina i sotsiatnaja organizat-sija u narodov Vostochnoj i Jugo-Vostochnoj Azii [Community and Social Organization of the East and Southeast Asian Peoples] (pp. 168-191). Leningrad: Nauka.
Byrd, B. F.
2000. Households in Transition. Neolithic Social Organization within Southwest Asia. In Kuijt, I. (ed.), Life in Neolithic Farming Communities. Social Organization, Identity, and Differentiation (pp. 63-98). New York etc.: Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers.
Carneiro, R. L.
1970. A Theory of the Origin of the State. Science 169: 733-738.
1981. The Chiefdom: Precursor of the State. In Jones, G. D., and Kautz, R. R. (eds.), The Transition to Statehood in the New World (pp. 37-79). Cambridge etc.: Cambridge University Press.
1998. What Happened at the Flashpoint? Conjectures on Chiefdom Formation at the Very Moment of Conception. In Redmond, E. M. (ed.), Chiefdoms and Chieftaincy in the Americas (pp. 18-42). Gainesville, FL etc.: University Press of Florida.
2000. Processes vs. Stages: A False Dichotomy in Tracing the Rise of the State. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 52-58.
2003. Evolutionism in Cultural Anthropology. A Critical History. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
2004. Multiple Trajectories in Political Development: Review of Jonathan Haas (ed.), From Leaders to Rulers. Social Evolution and History 3 (1): 162-175.
Chabal, P., Feinman, G., and Skalnik, P.
2004. Beyond States and Empires: Chiefdoms and Informal Politics.
Social Evolution and History 3 (1): 22-40.
Childe, V. G.
1942. What Happened in History. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.
Chipirova, L. A.
1988. Zemel'nye otnoshenija v semejnoj obshchine po 'Obelisku Manishtushu' [Land Relations in the Family Community by 'Obelisk of Manistusu']. Vestnik drevnej istorii 2: 3-35.
Christian, D.
2004. Maps of Time: An Introduction to Big History. Berkeley etc.: University of California Press.
Claessen, H. J. M.
1996. State. In Levinson, D., and Ember, M. (eds.), Encyclopedia of Cultural Anthropology. Vol. 4 (pp. 1253-1257). New York: Holt.
2000. Structural Change. Evolution and Evolutionism in Cultural Anthropology. Leiden: Leiden University.
2003. Aspects of Law and Order in Early State Societies. In Feld-brugge, F. J. M. (ed.), The Law's Beginnings (pp. 161-179). Leiden: Brill/Myhoff.
Claessen, H. J. M., and Oosten, J. G. (eds.)
1996. Ideology and the Formation of Early States. Leiden: Brill.
Claessen, H. J. M., and Skalnik, P. (eds.)
1978. The Early State. The Hague etc.: Mouton.
Claude, D.
1970. Geschichte der Westgoten. Stuttgart etc.: Kohlhammer Verlag.
Cohen, R.
1978. State Origins: A Reappraisal. In Claessen and Skalnik 1978 (pp. 31-75).
1981. Evolution, Fission, and the Early State. In Claessen, H. J. M., and Skalnik, P. (eds.), The Study of the State (pp. 87-116). The Hague etc.: Mouton.
Cole, H. M.
1981. Hierarchical Compositions as Religious Metaphors in Southern Nigerian Art. In Rovey, J., and Rubin, A. (eds.), Observations and Interpretations: 2000 Years of Nigerian Art (pp. 12-14). Los Angeles: African Studies Center, University of California - Los Angeles Occasional Papers, 23.
Cook, G.
2004. Heterarchy and Homoarchy in Maya Village Politics. In Alexeev, Beliaev, and Bondarenko 2004: 9-10.
Crumley, C. L.
1979. Three Locational Models: An Epistemological Assessment for Anthropology and Archaeology. In Schiffer, M. B. (ed.), Advances in Archaeological Method and Theory. Vol. 2 (pp. 141-173). New York: Academic Press.
1987. A Dialectical Critique of Hierarchy. In Patterson, Th. C., and Gailey, Ch. W. (eds.), Power Relations and State Formation (pp. 155-169). Washington, DC: American Anthropological Association Press.
1995. Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies. In Ehrenreich, Crumley, and Levy 1995: 1-5.
2001. Communication, Holism, and the Evolution of Sociopolitical Complexity. In Haas, J. (ed.), From Leaders to Rulers (pp. 19-33). New York; Boston: Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers.
Dapper, O.
1668/1975. Neurige Beschrijvinge der Afrikaensche Gewesten. In Hodgkin, Th. (ed.), The Nigerian Perspectives. An Historical Anthology (pp. 159-173). London etc.: Oxford University Press.
1671. Umständliche und eigentliche Beschreibung von Afrika. Amsterdam: Van Meurs.
Darling, P. J.
1984. Archaeology and History in Southern Nigeria. The Ancient Linear Earthworks of Benin and Ishan. Pts. 1-2. Oxford: British Archaeological Reports.
Dennett, R. E.
1910. Nigerian Studies Or The Religious and Political System of the Yoruba. London: Macmillan and Co.
Diakonoff, I. M.
1985. Extended Families in Old Babylonian Ur. Zeitschrift für Assy-riologie 75: 47-65.
Diakonoff, I. M., and Jakobson, V. A.
1998. Grazhdanskoe obshchestvo v drevnosti [Civil Society in Antiquity]. Vestnik drevnej istorii 1: 22-30.
Diakonoff, I. M., Neronova, V. D., and Sventsitskaja, I. S. (eds.)
1989. Istorija drevnego mira [Ancient History]. Vols. 1-3. Moscow: Nauka.
Dictionary
n.d. Web Dictionary of Cybernetics and Systems. http://pespmc1.vub.ac.be/ASC
Diesner, H.-J.
1966. Das Vandalenreich. Aufstieg und Untergang. Stuttgart etc.: Kohlhammer Verlag.
Dike, K. O.
1959. Benin - srednevekovoe gosudarstvo Nigerii [Benin, A Medieval Nigerian State]. Kur'er JuNESKO 10: 13-14.
Dozhdev, D. V.
2004. Rome: Socio-political Evolution in the 8th - 2nd Centuries B.C. In Grinin, Carneiro, Bondarenko, Kradin, and Korotayev 2004: 388-418.
Dräger, L.
1968. Formen der lokalen Organisation der Zentral-Algonkin von der Zeit ihrer Entdeckung bis zur Gegenwart. Berlin: Akademie-Verlag.
Duby, G.
1970. Struktura sem'i v srednevekovoj Zapadnoj Evrope [Family Structure in Medieval Western Europe]. Moscow: Nauka.
Dumont, L.
1966/1980. Homo Hierarchicus: The Caste System and Its Implications. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Dvoretskaja, I. A.
1982. Vozniknovenie rannefeodal'nogo gosudarstva v Severnoj Italii VI - VIII vekov [The Rise of the Early-feudal State in Northern Italy of the 6th - 8th Centuries]. Moscow: Moscow State Institute of Education Press.
Earle, T. K.
1978. Economic and Social Organization of a Complex Chiefdom: The Halelea District, Kaua 'i, Hawaii. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
1987. Chiefdoms in Archaeological and Ethnohistorical Perspective. Annual Review of Anthropology 16: 279-308.
1991. The Evolution of Chiefdoms. In Earle, T. K. (ed.), Chiefdoms: Power, Economy, and Ideology (pp. 1-15). Cambridge etc.: Cambridge University Press.
1994. Political Domination and Social Evolution. In Ingold, T. (ed.),
Companion Encyclopedia of Anthropology (pp. 940-961). London: Routledge.
1997. How Chiefs Come to Power. The Political Economy in Prehistory. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
2000. Hawaiian Islands (A.D. 800 -1824). In Bondarenko and Koro-tayev 2000a: 73-86.
Egharevba, J. U.
1949. Benin Law and Custom. Port Harcourt: Niger Press.
1952. The City of Benin. Benin City: Aguebor Printers.
1956. Bini Titles. Benin City: Kopin-Dogba Press.
1960. A Short History of Benin. Ibadan: Ibadan University Press.
Ehrenreich, R. M., Crumley, C. L., and Levy, J. E. (eds.)
1995. Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Societies. Washington, DC: American Anthropological Association Press.
Elimimian, I. I.
1986. Predominant Themes of Edo (Bini) Oral Poetry. Nigeria Magazine 54 (3): 104-111.
Ember, C. R., and Melvin, E.
1999. Cultural Anthropology. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Engels, F.
1884/1985. Proiskhozhdenie sem'i, chastnoj sobstvennosti i gosudarstva [The Origin of the Family, Private Property and the State]. Moscow: Politizdat.
Evans-Pritchard, E. E.
1940. The Nuer. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
1949. The Sanusi of Syrenaica. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Eweka, E. B.
1989. The Benin Monarchy: Origin and Development. Benin City: Bendel Newspapers.
1992. Evolution of Benin Chieftaincy Titles. Benin City: Uniben Press.
Eweka, I.
1998. Dawn to Dusk: Folk Tales from Benin. London; Portland, OR: Cass.
Fallers, L. A.
1956. Bantu Bureaucracy. A Century of Political Evolution among the Basoga of Uganda. Cambridge: Heffer.
Feinman, G. M.
1995. The Emergence of Inequality: A Focus on Strategies and Processes. In Price, T. D., and Feinman, G. M. (eds.), The Foundations of Social Inequality (pp. 255-279). New York: Plenum Press.
Feinman, G. M., and Marcus, J. (eds.)
1998. Archaic States. Santa Fe, NM: School of American Research Press.
Fine, J. V. A.
1983. The Ancient Greeks: A Critical History. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Finley, M. I.
1963. The Ancient Greecs: An Introduction to Their Life and Thouht. New York: Viking Press.
1981. Early Greece: The Bronze and Archaic Ages. New York: Norton.
1982. Authority and Legitimacy in the Classical City-State. Kopenhagen: Munksgaard.
Fortes, M., and Evans-Pritchard, E. E. (eds.)
1940/1987. African Political Systems. London; New York: KPI; International African Institute.
Freedman, M.
1958. Lineage Organisation in Southeastern China. London: Athlone Press.
Freud, S.
1911/1923. Totem i tabu [Totem and Taboo]. Petrograd: n.p.
Fried, M. H.
1960/1970. On the Evolution of Social Stratification and the State. In Laumann, E. O., Siegel, P. M., and Hodge, R. W. (eds.), The Logic of Social Hierarchies (pp. 684-695). Chicago: Markham.
1967. The Evolution of Political Society, An Essay in Political Anthropology. New York: Random House.
Frolov, E. D.
1988. Rozhdenie grecheskogo polisa [The Birth of the Greek Polis]. Leningrad: Leningrad State University Press.
Gallagher, J.
1983. Between Realms: The Iconography of Kingship in Benin. In Ben-Amos, P., and Rubin, A. (eds.), The Art of Power, the Power of Art: Studies in Benin Iconography (pp. 21-26). Los Angeles: Museum of Cultural History, University of California - Los Angeles.
Gallwey, H. L.
1892/1969. Report on Visit to Ubini (Benin City) the Capital of the Benin Country. In Ryder 1969, App. 9: 345-348.
1893. Journeys in the Benin Country, West Africa. Geographical Journal 1: 122-130.
Gelb, I. J.
1979. Household and Family in Early Mesopotamia. In Lipinski, E. (ed.),
State and Temple Economy in the Ancient Near East. Vol. 1 (pp. 1-97). Lou-vain: Peeters.
Genicot, L.
1968. Le XIIIe siècle européen. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
Gluckman, M.
1940/1987. The Kingdom of the Zulu of South Africa. In Fortes and Evans-Pritchard 1940/1987: 25-55.
Godiner, E. S.
1991. Politicheskaja antropologija o proiskhozhdenii gosudarstva [Political Anthropology and the Origin of the State]. In Kozlov, S. Ya., and Puchkov, P. I. (eds.), Etnologicheskaja nauka za rubezhom: prob-lemy, poiski, reshenija [Ethnology Abroad: Problems, Approaches, Solutions] (pp. 51-77). Moscow: Nauka.
Gomerov, I. N.
2002. Gosudarstvo i gosudarstvennaja vlast [The State and State Power]. Moscow: JuKEA.
Grinin, L. E.
1997. Formatsii i tsivilizatsii. Gl. 4. Sotsial'no-politicheskie, et-nicheskie i dukhovnye aspekty sotsiologii istorii [Formations and Civilizations. Ch. 4. Socio-political, Ethnic, and Spiritual Aspects of the Sociology of History]. Filosofija i obshchestvo 5: 5-64.
2000. Proizvoditel'nye sily i istoricheskij protsess [Productive Forces and Historical Process]. Moscow: Teis.
2004. Early State and Democracy. In Grinin, Carneiro, Bondarenko, Kradin, and Korotayev 2004: 419-463.
Grinin, L. E., Carneiro, R. L., Bondarenko, D. M., Kradin, N. N., and Korotayev, A. V. (eds.)
2004. The Early State, Its Alternatives and Analogues. Volgograd: Uchitel.
Guidi, A.
2002. Modelling the Social Evolution: The State of Art. Archeologia e Calcolatori 13: 65-78.
Gurevich, A.
1999. Izbrannye trudy [Selected Works]. Vol. 1. Drevnie germantsy. Vikingi [The Ancient Germans. The Vikings]. Moscow; St. Petersburg: Universitetskaja kniga.
Haggis, D., Terrenato, N., and Vander Poppen, R. (organizers)
2003. Current Issues in State Formation: The Mediterranean and Beyond. Colloquium, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, October 17-19, 2003. http://www.classics.unc.edu/wgems/index.html
Hansen, M. H.
1991. The Athenian Democracy in the Age of Demosthenes: Structure, Principles, and Ideology. Oxford: Blackwell.
Harding, A. F.
2000. European Societies in the Bronze Age. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Harris, M.
1968. The Rise of Anthropological Theory: A History of Theories of Culture. New York: Random House.
Hodgen, M. T.
1964. Early Anthropology in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Hopkins, K.
1968. Structural Differentiation in Rome (200 - 31 B.C.). The Genesis of a Historical Bureaucratic Society. In Lewis, I. M. (ed.), History and Social Anthropology (pp. 63-79). London: Tavistock.
Horn, F. (ed.)
1998. Economic, Social and Cultural Rights of the Maasai. Ro-vaniemi: Lapland's University Press.
Igbafe, Ph. A.
1975. Benin in the Pre-colonial Era. Tarikh 5: 1-16.
1979. Benin under British Administration: The Impact of Colonial Rule on an African Kingdom, 1897 - 1938. London: Humanities Press.
Iljushechkin, V. P.
1986. Teorija stadijnogo razvitija obshchestva (istorija i problemy)
[The Theory of Society's Onward Development (History and Problems)]. Moscow: Vostochnaja literatura.
1990. Ekspluatatsija i sobstvennost' v soslovno-klassovykh obshchest-vakh (Opyt sistemno-strukturnogo issledovanija) [Exploitation and Property in Estate-Class Societies (A Systemic-Structural Study)]. Moscow: Nauka.
Imoagene, O.
1990. The Edo and Their Neighbours. Ibadan: New-Era Educational Company.
Ingram, A.
1588/1904. A Relation Concerning a Voyage Set Foorth by M. John Newton, and M. John Bird, Merchants of London to the Kingdoms and Citie of Benin. Anno 1588. In Hakluyt, R. (publ.), The Principal Navigations, Voyages, Traffiques and Discoveries of the English Nation. Vol. 4 (pp. 297-302). Glasgow: Hakluyt Society.
Irons, W.
1975. The Yomut Turkmen: A Study of Social Organization among a Central Asian Turkic-speaking Population. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
1994. Why Are the Yomut Not More Stratified? In Chang, C., and Koster, H. A. (eds.), Pastoralists at the Periphery (pp. 175-196). Tucson, AZ; London: University of Arizona Press.
Jajlenko, V. P.
1983. Archaic Greece. In Golubtsova, E. S. (ed.), Antichnaja Gret-sija. Problemy razvitija polisa [Ancient Greece. Problems of the Polis' Development]. Vol. 1. Stanovlenie i razvitie polisa [Formation and Development of the Polis] (pp. 128-193). Moscow: Nauka.
Jakobson, V. A. (ed.)
1997. Istoija Vostoka [History of the East]. Vol. 1. Vostok v drevnosti [The East in Antiquity]. Moscow: Nauka.
Johnson, A. W., and Earle, T.
2000. The Evolution of Human Societies. From Foraging Group to Agrarian State. 2nd ed. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Jolly, M., and Mosko, M. S. (guest eds.)
1994. Transformations of Hierarchy. Structure, History and Horizon in the Austronesian World. History and Anthropology 7: 1-409.
Jones, A.
1983. German Sources for West African History 1599 - 1669. Wiesbaden: Steiner Verlag.
Kalous, M.
1970. The Economic and Political Structure of the Benin Kingdom.
Afrika und Übersee 53 (2): 83-122.
Kammerer, C. A.
1998. Descent, Alliance, and Political Order among Akha. American Ethnologist 25: 659-674.
Karpjuk, S. G.
1994. [Review of O. Murray. Early Greece. 2nd ed. London: Fontana Press, 1993]. Vestnik drevnej istorii 2: 192-194.
Kelly, R. C.
1993. Constructing Inequality. The Fabrication of a Hierarchy of Virtue among the Etoro. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
Khazanov, A. M.
1968. Voennaja demokratija i epokha klassoobrazovanija [Military Democracy and the Epoch of Class Formation]. Voprosy istorii 12: 87-97.
1994. Nomads and the Outside World. 2nd ed. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.
Kituyi, M.
1990. Becoming Kenyan: Socio-economic Transformation of the Pastoral Maasai. Nairobi: African Centre for Technology Studies Press.
Kochakova, N. B.
1970. Osobennosti proizvodstva i prisvoenija pribavochnogo pro-dukta v stranakh Beninskogo zaliva (traditsionnye formy) [Specific Features of Surplus Product Production and Acquisition in the Bight of Benin Countries (Traditional Forms)]. In Kobishchanov, Yu. M., and Kubbel, L. E. (eds.), Sotsial'nye struktury dokolonial'noj Afriki [Pre-colonial African Social Structures] (pp. 17-67). Moscow: Nauka.
1986. Rozhdenie afrikanskoj tsivilizatsii: Ife, Ojo, Benin, Dagomeja [The Birth of an African Civilization: Ife, Oyo, Benin, Dahomey]. Moscow: Nauka.
1991. Gerontokratija. Vozrastnoj printsip poluchenija vlasti [Gerontocracy. The Age-based Principle of Getting Power]. In Geveling, L. V. (ed.), Mekhanizmy poluchenija vlasti v stranakh Zapadnoj Afriki [Mechanisms of Getting Power in West African Countries] (pp. 17-25). Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
1994. Problemy ideologii rannego gosudarstva perekhodnogo tipa [On Ideology of the Transitional Early State]. Vostok/Oriens 5: 22-32.
1996a. Dvadtsatiletie issledovatel'skogo proekta 'Rannee gosudar-stvo' [The Twentieth Anniversary of 'The Early State' Research Project]. Vostok/Oriens 4: 191-199.
1996b. The Sacred Ruler as the Ideological Centre of an Early State: The Precolonial States of the Bight of Benin Coast. In Claessen and Oosten 1996: 48-65.
1999. Rannee gosudarstvo i Afrika (analiticheskij obzor publikatsij Mezhdunarodnogo issledovatel'skogo proekta 'Rannee gosudarstvo')
[The Early State and Africa (An Analytic Review of 'The Early State' International Research Project Publications)]. Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
Korotayev, A. V.
1990. Rodovaja organizatsija v sotsial'no-ekonomicheskoj strukture sabejskogo obshchestva (opyt kolichestvennogo analiza juzhnoaravijskoj epigrafiki) [Clan Organization in Socio-economic Structure of the Sabaean Society (A Quantitative Analysis of South Arabian Epigraphic Sources)]. Ph.D. dissertation. Moscow: Institute of Oriental Studies.
1995. Mountains and Democracy: An Introduction. In Kradin, N. N., and Lynsha, V. A. (eds.), Alternative Pathways to Early Statehood (pp. 60-74). Vladivostok: Dal'nauka.
1996. Pre-Islamic Yemen. Sociopolitical Organization of the Sabaean Cultural Area in the 2nd and 3rd Centuries A.D. Wiesbaden: Horrosowitz Verlag.
2000. Northeast Yemen (1st and 2nd Millennia A.D.). In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a: 188-225.
2003. Unilineal Descent Organization and Deep Christianization: A Cross-Cultural Comparison. Cross-Cultural Research 37: 133-157.
2004. World Religions and Social Evolution of the Old World Oiku-mene Civilizations. A Cross-Cultural Perspective. Lewiston, MN etc.: The Edwin Mellen Press.
Korotayev, A. V., and Bondarenko, D. M.
2000. Polygyny and Democracy: A Cross-Cultural Comparison.
Cross-Cultural Research 34: 190-208.
Korotayev, A. V., Kradin, N. N., de Munck, V., and Lynsha, V. A.
2000. Alternativity of Social Evolution: Introductory Notes. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 12-51.
Korotayev, A. V., and Obolonkov, A. A.
1989. Rodovaja organizatsija v sotsial'no-ekonomicheskoj strukture klassovykh obshchestv [Unilineal Descent Organization in the Socioeconomic Structure of Class Societies]. Sovetskaja etnografija 2: 36-45.
Kowalewski, S. A.
2000. Cyclical Transformations in North American Prehistory. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 177-187.
2003. What is the Community? The Long View from Oaxaca, Mexico. Social Evolution and History 2 (1): 4-24.
Kradin, N. N.
1991. Politogenez [State Formation]. In Korotayev, A. V., and Chu-barov, V. V. (eds.), Arkhaicheskoe obshchestvo: uzlovye problemy sotsi-ologii razvitija [Archaic Society: Some Basic Problems of the Sociology
of Evolution]. Vol. 2 (pp. 261-300). Moscow: Institute of History of the USSR Press.
1998. 'Rannee gosudarstvo': kljuchevye aspekty kontseptsii i nekoto-rye momenty ejo istorii ['The Early State': Key Aspects of the Concept and Some Episodes of Its History]. In Sledzevski, I. V., and Bondarenko, D. M. (eds.), Afrika: obshchestva, kul'tury, jazyki [Africa: Societies, Cultures, Languages] (pp. 4-15). Moscow: Institute for African Studies Press.
2000a. Nomadic Empires in Evolutionary Perspective. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 274-288.
2000b. The Hsiung-Nu (200 B.C. - A.D. 48). In Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000a: 287-304.
2002. Nomadism, Evolution, and World-Systems: Pastoral Societies in Theories of Historical Development. Journal of World-System Research 8: 368-388 (http://csf.colorado.edu/jwsr).
2003. Nomadic Empires: Origins, Rise, Decline. In Kradin, N. N., Bondarenko, D. M., and Barfield, T. J. (eds.), Nomadic Pathways in Social Evolution (pp. 73-87). Moscow: Center for Civilization and Regional Studies Press.
2004. Politicheskaja antropologija [Political Anthropology]. Moscow: Logos.
Kradin, N. N., Korotayev, A. V., Bondarenko, D. M., de Munck, V., and Wason, P. K. (eds.)
2000. Alternatives of Social Evolution. Vladivostok: Far Eastern Branch of the Russian Academy of Sciences Press.
Kristiansen, K.
1991. Chiefdoms, States, and Systems of Social Evolution. In Earle, T. K. (ed.), Chiefdoms: Power, Economy, and Ideology (pp. 16-43). Cambridge etc.: Cambridge University Press.
1998. Europe before History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ksenofontova, N. A.
1970. Mashona. Traditsionnye sotsial'nye svjazi v obshchine [The Masho-na. Traditional Social Ties in the Community]. In Kobishchanov, Yu. M., and Kubbel, L. E. (eds.), Sotsial'nye struktury dokolonial'noj Afriki [Pre-colonial African Social Structures] (pp. 174-197). Moscow: Nauka.
Kuijt, I.
2000. Near Eastern Neolithic Research. Directions and Trends. In Kuijt, I. (ed.), Life in Neolithic Farming Communities. Social Organization, Identity, and Differentiation (pp. 311-323). New York etc.: Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers.
Kuzishchin, V. I. (ed.)
1999. Istorija drevnego Vostoka [History of the Ancient East]. Moscow: Vysshaja shkola.
Leach, E. R.
1954. Political Systems of Highland Burma. A Study of Kachin Social Structure. Boston: Beacon Press.
Lenin, V. I.
1917/1974. Gosudarstvo i revoljutsija [State and Revolution]. In V. I. Lenin, Polnoe sobranie sochinenij [Collected Works]. Vol. 33 (pp. 1-120). Moscow: Politicheskaja literatura.
Leonard, A. G.
1906. The Lower Niger and Its Tribes. London: Macmillan.
Levy, J. E.
1995. Heterarchy in Bronze Age Denmark: Settlement Pattern, Gender, and Ritual. In Ehrenreich, Crumley, and Levy 1995: 41-53.
Lewis, I. M.
1965. Problems in the Comparative Study of Unilineal Descent. In Banton, M. (ed.), The Relevance of Models for Social Anthropology (pp. 87-112). London: Tavistock.
Lowie, R. H.
1920. Primitive Society. New York: Boni and Liveright.
1935. The Crow Indians. New York: Farrar and Rinehart.
1948. Social Organization. New York: Rinehart.
Maine, H. S.
1861. Ancient Law. Its Connection with the Early History of Society and Its Relation to Modern Ideas. London: Murray.
1880. Lectures on the Early History of Institutions. 3rd ed. London: Murray.
Mair, L.
1965. An Introduction to Social Anthropology. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Maisels, Ch. K.
1987. Models of Social Evolution: Trajectories from the Neolithic to the State. Man (N.S.) 22: 331-359.
1990. The Emergence of Civilization. London: Routledge.
Mann, M.
1986. The Sources of Social Power. Vol. 1. A History of Power from the Beginning to A.D. 1760. Cambridge etc.: Cambridge University Press.
Manning, P.
1986. Hegelian Dialectics in Benin Kingdom Historiography. Canadian Journal of African Studies 20: 43-435.
Marcus, J., and Feinman, G. M.
1998. Introduction. In Feinman and Marcus 1998: 1-13.
McCulloch, M., Littlewood, M., and Dugast, I.
1954. Peoples of the Central Cameroons. Tikar, Bamum and Bamileke, Banen, Bafia and Balom. London: International African Institute Press.
Mcintosh, S. K. (ed.)
1999. Beyond Chiefdoms. Pathways to Complexity in Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
McNeill, W. H.
1963. The Rise of the West. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Melzian, H. J.
1937. A Concise Dictionary of the Bini Language of Southern Nigeria. London: Paul, Trench, Trubner and Co.
Mercier, P.
1962. Civilisations du Bénin. Paris: Societé continentale d'éditions modernes illustries.
Middleton, J., and Tait, D. (eds.)
1958. Tribes without Rulers. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Millar, H.
1997. The Kingdom of Benin in West Africa. Tarrytown, NY: Benchmark Books.
Milner, G. R.
1998. The Cahokia Chiefdom: The Archaeology of a Mississippian Society. Washington, DC; London: Smithsonian Institution Press.
Morgan, L. H.
1851. The League of the Ho-de-no-sau-nee, or Iroquois. Rochester, NY: Sage.
1877. Ancient Society, Or Researches in the Lines of Human Progress from Savagery through Barbarism to Civilization. Cleveland, OH: World Publishing Company.
Morony, M. G.
1987. 'In the City without Watchdogs the Fox is the Overseer': Issues and Problems in the Study of Bureaucracy. In McGuire, G., and Biggs, R. D. (eds.), The Organization of Power Aspects of Bureaucracy in the Ancient Near East (pp. 7-18). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Mosko, M. S.
1994a. Junior Chiefs and Senior Sorcerers: The Contradictions and Inversions of Mekeo Hierarchy. In Jolly and Mosko 1994: 19-222.
1994b. Transformations of Dumont: The Hierarchical, the Sacred, and the Profane in India and Ancient Hawaii. In Jolly and Mosko 1994: 1-86.
Mossé, C.
1969. La tyrannie dans la Grèce antique. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
Mudar, K. M.
1999. How many Dvaravati Kingdoms? Locational Analysis of First Millennium A.D. Moated Settlements in Central Thailand. Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 18: 1-28.
Murdock, G. P., and Wilson, S. F.
1972. Settlement Patterns and Community Organization: Cross-Cultural Codes 3. Ethnology 11: 254-295.
Murray, O.
1993. Early Greece. 2nd ed. London: Fontana Press.
Nangoro, B. N. Ole
1998. 'Branding the Land': Maasai Responses to Resource Tenure Insecurity and Social Change. In Horn 1998: 15-93.
Nersesjants, V. S. (ed.)
1985. Istorija politicheskikh i pravovykh uchenij (Drevnij mir) [History of Political and Legal Teachings (Antiquity)]. Moscow: Nauka.
1986. Istorija politicheskikh i pravovykh uchenij (Srednie veka i Vozrozhdenie) [History of Political and Legal Teachings (The Middle Ages and Renaissance)]. Moscow: Nauka.
Nevadomsky, J.
1993. The Benin Kingdom: Rituals of Kingship and Their Social Meanings. African Study Monographs 14: 65-77.
Nikol'skij, N. M. (ed.)
1914. Istorija evrejskogo naroda [A History of the Jewish People]. Vol. 1. Drevnejshaja epokha evrejskoj istorii [Most Ancient Period of Jewish History]. Moscow: Mir.
Nkanta, M. A., and Arinze, E. N. n.d. The Lost Treasures of Ancient Benin. n.l.: n.p.
Nwankwo, J. C.
1987. Land Custom and Social Structure of Rural Nigeria prior to Colonialism. Nigeria Magazine 55: 47-50.
Obayemi, A.
1976. The Yoruba and Edo-speaking Peoples and Their Neighbours before 1600. In Ajayi, J. F. A., and Crowder, M. (eds.), History of West Africa. Vol. 1 (pp. 196-263). London: Longman.
Ogbobine, R. A. I.
1974. Materials and Cases on Benin Land Law. Benin City: Midwest Newspapers.
Oghieriakhi, E.
1965. My Wife or My Wives: The Marriage Could Not Continue. Benin City: Kopin-Dogba Press.
Omijeh, M. E. A.
1971. The Significance of Orhue in Bini Symbolism. Nigeria Magazine 107-109: 117-119.
Oosten, J. G.
1996. Ideology and the development of European kingdoms. In Claessen and Oosten 1996: 220-241.
Oosten, J. G., and van de Velde, P.
1994. Constructing the Early State: The Rise of a Research Programme. In Bakel, M. van, Hagesteijn, R., and Velde, P. van de (eds.), Pivot Politics. Changing Cultural Identities in Early State Formation Processes (pp. 7-21). Amsterdam: Het Spinhuis.
Otto, K.-H., and Horst, F.
1982. Die Stämme und Stammesgruppen der Bronzezeit und die Herausbildung von Verhältnissen der militärischen Demokratie (Beginn des 2. Jahrtausends bis 8. Jahrhundert v.u.Z.). Berlin: Akdemie-Verlag.
Palat, R. A.
1987. The Vijayanagara Empire. Re-integration of the Agrarian Order of Medieval South India, 1336 - 1565. In Claessen, H. J. M., and Velde, P. van de (eds.), Early State Dynamics (pp. 170-186). Leiden: Brill.
Palau Marti, M.
1960. Essai sur la notion de roi. Chez lesyoruba et les aja-fon (Nigeria et Dahomey). These de 3e cycle. Paris: Université de Paris.
Paque, V.
1954. Les Bambara. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
Parsons, T.
1960. Structure and Process in Modern Societies. New York: Free Press.
1966. Societies: Evolutionary and Comparative Perspectives. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Pauketat, T. R.
1994. The Ascent of Chiefs: Cahokia and Mississippian Politics in Native North America. Tuscaloosa, AL; London: University of Alabama Press.
Pearson, R.
2001. Archaeological Perspectives on the Rise of the Okinawan State.
Journal of Archaeological Research 9: 243-285.
Peebles, Ch. S., and Kus, S.
1977. Some Archaeological Correlates of Ranked Societies. American Antiquity 42: 421-448.
Pershits, A. I.
1986. Demokratija voennaja [Military Democracy]. In Pershits, A. I., and Treide, D. (eds.), Svod etnograficheskikh ponjatij i terminov [Compen-
dium of Ethnographic Notions and Terms]. Vol. 1. SotsiaFno-ekonomicheskie otnoshenija i sotsionormativnaja kuFtura [Socio-economic Relations and Socionormative culture] (pp. 47-48). Moscow: Nauka.
Possehl, G. L.
1998. Sociocultural Complexity without the State. The Indus Civilization. In Feinman and Marcus 1998: 261-291.
Potter, S. R.
1993. Commoners, Tribute, and Chiefs: The Development of Algon-quian Culture in the Potomac Valley. Charlottesville, VA: University Press of Virginia.
Quigley, D.
1995. The Paradoxes of Monarchy. Anthropology Today 11 (5): 1-3.
1999. The Interpretation of Caste. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Read, C. H.
1904. Notes on the Form of the Bini Government. Man 4: 50-54.
Rebrikova, N. V.
1987. Gosudarstvo, obshchina, klass v buddijskikh obshchestvakh Tsentral'nogo Indokitaja (V - XV vv.) [State, Community, Class in Buddhist Societies of Central Indo-China (5th - 15th Centuries). In Kim, G. F., and Ashrafjan, K. Z. (eds.), Gosudarstvo v dokapitalisticheskikh obshchestvakh Azii [The State in Pre-capitalist Asian Societies] (pp. 158-180). Moscow: Nauka.
Redmond, E. M.
1998. The Dynamics of Chieftaincy and the Development of Chiefdoms. In Redmond, E. M. (ed.), Chiefdoms and Chieftaincy in the Americas (pp. 1-17). Gainesville, FL etc.: University Press of Florida.
Reiher, D.
2004. Pyramid and Trapeze Constellations; State-building Processes and Patterns of Social Control. In Alexeev, Beliaev, and Bondarenko 2004: 15-16.
Roese, P. M.
1988. Die Hierarchie des ehemaligen Königreiches Benin aus der Sicht zeitgenössischer europäischer Beobachter. EthnographischArchäologische Zeitschrift 29: 47-73.
1993. Palastbedienstete, Zünfte, Heilkundige, Priester und weitere Gruppen sowie Einzelpersonen mit spezifischen Funktionen im ehemaligen Königreich Benin (Westafrika). Ethnographisch-Archäologische Zeitschrift 34: 436-461.
Roese, P. M., and Bondarenko, D. M.
2003. A Popular History of Benin. The Rise and Fall of a Mighty Forest Kingdom. Frankfurt am Main etc.: Lang.
Roese, P. M., and Rees, A. R.
1994. Aspects of Farming and Farm Produce in the History of Benin (West Africa). Ethnographisch-Archäologische Zeitschrift 35: 538-572.
Roese, P. M., and Reichel, W.
1990. Louis Jacolliots Aufenthalt in Benin und Ijebu im Jahre 1871 -ein wenig bekannter zeitgenössischer Bericht. Abhandlungen und Berichte des Staatlichen Museums für Völkerkunde Dresden 44: 383-411.
Romano, D.
1987. Patricians and Popolani: The Social Foundations of the Venetian Renaissance State. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Roscoe, P. B.
1993. Practice and Political Centralisation. Current Anthropology 34: 111-124.
Roth, H. L.
1903/1968. Great Benin. Its Customs, Art and Horrors. London: Routledge and Paul Kegan.
Rouch, J.
1954. Les Songhay. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
Rountree, H. C., and Turner, E. R. III
1998. The Evolution of the Powhatan Paramount Chiefdom in Virginia. In Redmond, E. M. (ed.), Chiefdoms and Chieftaincy in the Americas (pp. 265-296). Gainesville, FL etc.: University Press of Florida.
Ryder, A. F. C.
1969. Benin and the Europeans. 1485 - 1897. London; Harlow: Longman.
Sahlins, M. D.
1960. Evolution: Specific and General. In Sahlins, M. D., and Service, E. R. (eds.), Evolution and Culture (pp. 12-44). Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
1963. Poor Man, Rich Man, Big Man, Chief: Political types in Melanesia and Polynesia. Comparative Studies in Society and History 5: 285-303.
Salzman, Ph. C.
1999. Is Inequality Universal? Current Anthropology 40: 31-44.
Samozvantsev, A. M.
2001. Sotsial'no-pravovaja organizatsija indijskogo obshchestva v kontse I tys. do n.e. - pervoj polovine I tys. n.e. [The Socio-legal Organization of Indian Society in the Late 1st Millennium B.C. - First Half of the 1st Millennium A.D.]. In Leljukhin, D. N., and Ljubimov, Yu. V. (eds.), Gosudarstvo v istorii obshchestva. K probleme kriteriev gosudarstven-nosti [State in the History of Society. On the Problem of the Statehood Criteria] (pp. 259-292). Moscow: Institute of Oriental Studies Press.
Sanderson, S. K.
2003. Review of Robert L. Carneiro, Evolutionism in Cultural Anthropology: A Critical History. Social Evolution and History 3 (2): 176-185.
Sargent, R. A.
1986. From a Redistribution to an Imperial Social Formation: Benin ca. 1293 - 1536. Canadian Journal of African Studies 20: 402-427.
Scarborough, V. L., Valdez, F., Jr., and Dunning, N. (eds.)
2003. Heterarchy, Political Economy, and the Ancient Maya. The Three Rivers Region of the East-Central Yucatán Peninsula. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press.
Schapera, I.
1956. Government and Politics in Tribal Society. London: Watts.
Schoenfelder, J. W.
2003. Negotiating Poise in a Multi-Hierarchical World: An Archaeological Exploration of Irrigated Rice Agriculture, Ideology, and Political Balances in the Coevolution of Intersecting Complex Networks in Bali. Ph.D. dissertation. Los Angeles: University of California.
Schurtz, H.
1902. Alterklassen und Männerbünde. Eine Darstellung der Grundformen der Gesellschaft. Berlin: Reimer.
Service, E. R.
1962/1971. Primitive Social Organization: An Evolutionary Perspective. New York: Random House.
1975. Origins of the State and Civilization: The Process of Cultural Evolution. New York: Norton.
1978. Classical and Modern Theories of the Origins of Government. In Cohen, R., and Service, E. R. (eds.), Origins of the State: The Anthropology of Political Evolution (pp. 21-34). Philadelphia: Institute for the Study of Human Issues Press.
Sharevskaja, B. I.
1957. Religii drevnego Benina (ocherk verovanij i kul'tov afrikan-skogo gosudarstva dokolonial'nogo perioda) [Religions of Ancient Benin (A Review of Beliefs and Cults of a Pre-colonial African State)]. Ezhe-godnik Muzeja istorii religii i ateizma 1: 172-213.
Shifferd, P. A.
1987. Aztecs and Africans: Political Processes in Twenty-two Early States. In Claessen, H. J. M., and Velde, P. van de (eds.), Early State Dynamics (pp. 39-53). Leiden: Brill.
Shkunaev, S. V.
1988. Kel'ty v Zapadnoj Evrope v V - I vv. [Celts in Western Europe in the 5th - 1st Centuries]. In Golubtsova, E. S. (ed.), Istorija Evropy [His-
tory of Europe]. Vol. 1. Drevnjaja Evropa [Ancient Europe] (pp. 492-503). Moscow: Nauka.
Shtaerman, E. M.
1989. K probleme vozniknovenija gosudarstva v Rime [On the Problem of Rise of the State in Rome]. Vestnik drevnej istorii 2: 76-94.
Sidahome, J. E.
1964. Stories of the Benin Empire. London; Ibadan: Oxford University Press.
Simonse, S.
2002. Kingship as a Lever versus the State as a Killer of Suspense. Some Lessons from the Study of Early Kingship on the Upper Nile. Paper presented in the Conference 'Kingship. A Comparative Approach to Monarchy from History and Ethnography'. University of St. Andrews, Fife, UK.
Skalník, P.
2002. Chiefdoms and Kingdoms in Africa: Why They are neither States nor Empires. http://asc.leidenuniv.nl/pdf/chiefdomsandkingdoms.pdf.
Small, D. B.
1995. Heterarchical Paths to Evolution: The Role of External Economies. In Ehrenreich, Crumley, and Levy 1995: 71-85.
Smith, M. E.
1985. An Aspectual Analysis of Polity Formations. In Claessen, H. J. M., with Velde, P. van de, and Smith, M. E. (eds.), Development and Decline. The Evolution of Sociopolitical Organization (pp. 97-125). South Hadley, MA: Bergin and Garvey.
Smith, R. C.
1985. The Clans of Athens and the Historiography of the Archaic Period. Classical Views 4: 77-105.
Smith, W.
1744. A New Voyage to Guinea. Describing Its Customs, Manners, Soil, Climate, Habits, Buildings, Education, Manual Arts, Agriculture, Trade, Employments, Languages, Ranks of Distinction, Habitations, Diversions, Marriages and Whatever Else is Memorable among the Inhabitants Likewise an Account of Their Animals, Minerals, etc. London: Nourse.
Southall, A.
1956. Alur Society: A Study in Processes and Types of Domination. Cambridge: Heffer.
1988. The Segmentary State in Africa and Asia. Comparative Studies in Society and History 30: 52-82.
1999. The Segmentary State and the Ritual Phase in Political Economy. In Mcintosh 1999: 31-38.
2000. On the Emergence of States. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 150-153.
Spencer, Ch. S.
1987. Rethinking the Chiefdom. In Drennan, R. D., and Uribe, C. A. (eds.), Chiefdoms in the Americas (pp. 369-390). Lanham, MD: University Press of America.
1998. A Mathematical Model of Primary State Formation. Cultural Dynamics 10: 5-20.
2003. War and Early State Formation in Oaxaca, Mexico. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA 100: 11185-11187.
Stein, B.
1989. Vijayanagara. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Stein, G. J.
1998. Heterogeneity, Power, and Political Economy: Some Current Research Issues in the Archaeology of Old World Complex Societies.
Journal of Archaeological Research 6: 1-44.
Strogetskij, V. M.
1995. Grazhdanskij kollektiv polisa (problemy stanovlenija i osoben-nosti razvitija v arkhaicheskij i ranneklassicheskij periody) [The Civil Collectivity of the Polis (Problems of Rise and Specifics of Development in Archaic and Early Classic Periods)]. In Frolov, E. D. (ed.), Antichnyj polis. Problemy sotsial'no-politicheskoj organizatsii i ideologii antich-nogo obshchestva [Antique Polis. Problems of Socio-political Organization and Ideology of the Antique Society] (pp. 3-12). Saint Petersburg: Saint Petersburg University Press.
Tainter, J. A.
1990. The Collapse of Complex Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Talbot, P. A.
1926. The Peoples of Southern Nigeria. A Sketch of Their History, Ethnology and Languages. Vols 1-4. London: Oxford University Press.
Tanabe, A.
1996. Indigenous Power, Hierarchy and Dominance: State Formation in Orissa, India. In Claessen and Oosten 1996: 154-165.
Tardits, C.
1980. Le royaume Bamoum. Paris: Colin.
Thevenot, E.
1996. Histoire des Gaulois. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
Thomas, N. W.
1910. Anthropological Report on the Edospeaking Peoples of Nigeria. Pts. 1-2. London: Harrison and Sons.
Trigger, B. G.
1985. Generalized Coercion and Inequality: The Basis of State Power in the Early Civilizations. In Claessen, H. J. M., Velde, P. van de, and Smith, M. E. (eds.), Development and Decline. The Evolution of Sociopolitical Organization (pp. 46-61). South Hadley, MA: Bergin and Garvey.
1993. Early Civilizations: Ancient Egypt in Context. Cairo: The American University in Cairo Press.
Tumans, H.
2002. Rozhdenie Afiny. Afinskij put' k demokratii: ot Gomera do Perikla (VIII- Vvv. do n.e.) [The Birth of Athena. The Athenian Pathway to Democracy: From Homer to Pericles (8th - 5th Centuries B.C.)]. Saint Petersburg: Gumanitarnaja akademija.
Tymowski, M.
1996. Oral Tradition, Dynastic Legend and Legitimation of Ducal Power in the Process of the Formation of the Polish State. In Claessen and Oosten 1996: 242-255.
Upham, S. (ed.)
1990. The Evolution of Political Systems. Sociopolitics in Small-scale Sedentary Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Van Nyendael, D.
1705. Letter to William Bosman, Dated 1st September. In William Bosman, A New and Accurate Description of the Coast of Guinea Divided into the Gold, the Slave and the Ivory Coast (pp. 423-468). London: Knapton.
Vliet, E. C. L. van der
1987. Tyranny and Democracy. The Evolution of Politics in Ancient Greece. In Claessen, H. J. M., and Velde, P. van de (eds.), Early State Dynamics (pp. 70-90). Leiden etc.: Brill.
1994. Poetry and the Emergence of the Polis. In Bakel, M. van, Hagesteijn, R., and Velde, P. van de (eds.), Pivot Politics. Changing Cultural Identities in Early State Formation Processes (pp. 87-100). Amsterdam: Het Spinhuis.
2003. Complexity and Heterarcy: The Archaic Greek Polis. http://www.classics.unc.edu/wgems/abstract12.html
Wailes, B.
1995. A Case Study of Heterarchy in Complex Societies: Early Medieval Ireland and Its Archaeological Implications. In Ehrenreich, Crumley, and Levy 1995: 56-69.
Wason, P. K.
1995. Social Types and the Limits of Typological Thinking in Social Archaeology. In Kradin, N. N., and Lynsha, V. A. (eds.), Alternative Pathways to Early Statehood (pp. 19-27). Vladivostok: Dal'nauka.
Wason, P. K., and Baldia, M. O.
2000. Religion, Communication, and the Genesis of Social Complexity in the European Neolithic. In Kradin, Korotayev, Bondarenko, de Munck, and Wason 2000: 138-148.
Watson, P. J.
1978. Architectural Differentiation in Some Near Eastern Communities, Prehistoric and Contemporary. In Redman, Ch. L., Berman, M. J., Curtin, E. V., Langhorne, Jr., W. T., Versaggi, N. M., and Wanser, J. C. (eds.), Social Archaeology: Beyond Subsistence and Dating (pp. 131158). New York: Academic Press.
Webb, M.
1975. The Flag Follows the Trade: An Essay on the Necessary Interaction of Military and Commercial Factors in State Formation. In Sabloff, J. A., and Lamberg-Karlovsky, C. C. (eds.), Ancient Civilization and Trade (pp. 155-209). Albuquerque, NM: School of American Research.
Weber, M.
1922/1947. The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. New York: Oxford University Press.
1978. Economy and Society. Vols. 1-2. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Whitaker, Ia.
1968. Tribal Structure and National Politics in Albania, 1910 - 1950. In Lewis, I. M. (ed.), History and Social Anthropology (pp. 253-293). London: Tavistock.
White, J. C.
1995. Incorporating Heterarchy into Theory on Socio-Political Development: The Case from Southeast Asia. In Ehrenreich, Crumley, and Levy 1995: 101-123.
Wilkinson, T. A. H.
1999. Early Dynastic Egypt. London: Routledge.
Wilks, I.
1986. R. A. Sargent: 'From a Redistribution to an Imperial Social Formation: Benin ca. 1293 - 1536'. Canadian Journal of African Studies 20: 436-438.
Wright, H. T.
1977. Recent Research on the Origin of the State. Annual Review of Anthropology 6: 379-397.
Yoffee, N.
1993. Too Many Chiefs? (Or, Safe Texts for the '90s). In Yoffee, N., and Sherratt, A. (eds.), Archaeological Theory: Who Sets the Agenda? (pp. 60-78). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zak, S. D.
1975. Metodologicheskie problemy izuchenija sel'skoj pozemel'noj obshchiny [Methodological Problems of the Agricultural Territorial Community Study]. In Olderogge, D. A., and Maretina, S. A. (eds.), Sot-sial'naja organizatsija narodov Azii i Afriki [Social Organization of Asian and African Peoples] (pp. 233-311). Moscow: Nauka.
Zannini, A.
1993. Burocrazia e burocrati a Venezia in età moderna: I cittadini origi-nari (secoli XVI -XVIII). Venezia: Istituto veneto di scienze, lettere ed arti.
Zotova, Yu. N.
1979. Traditsionnye politicheskie instituty Nigerii. Pervaja polovina XX v. [Traditional Political Institutions of Nigeria. First Half of the 20th Century]. Moscow: Nauka.